About this Journal Submit a Manuscript Table of Contents
Abstract and Applied Analysis
Volume 2013 (2013), Article ID 836537, 6 pages
http://dx.doi.org/10.1155/2013/836537
Research Article

Nonlinear Dynamics in the Solow Model with Bounded Population Growth and Time-to-Build Technology

1Department of Management, Polytechnic University of Marche, Piazza Martelli 8, 60121 Ancona, Italy
2Department of Economics and Management, University of Pisa, Via Cosimo Ridolfi 10, 56124 Pisa, Italy

Received 5 September 2013; Accepted 15 October 2013

Academic Editor: Carlo Bianca

Copyright © 2013 Luca Guerrini and Mauro Sodini. This is an open access article distributed under the Creative Commons Attribution License, which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited.

Abstract

The aim of this paper is to show that the Solow model equipped by realistic assumptions on technology and population dynamics is capable of explaining a well-known stylised fact of growth, that is, the presence of persistent oscillations of demoeconomic variables. In particular, our analysis shows that the coexistence of delays between (i) new investment and production and (ii) the birth date and the recruitment in the labour force is a source of cyclical behaviour in capital accumulation.

1. Introduction

Following a long tradition, the theory of economic growth is nevertheless mostly concerned with constant population growth rates. There are only a few theoretical papers that consider more complex and realistic assumption on population dynamics. For example, Guerrini [1] generalizes the result of existence and global stability of the (stationary) equilibrium in the Solow model by assuming a bounded, but not necessarily constant, population growth rate; Fanti and Manfredi [2] show in a Solow-type model that the existence of distributed delays (age structure) that influence the labour force and a Malthusian mechanism that relates fertility and wage rates are sources of fluctuations in growth paths; and Fabião and Borges [3] study the effects of fluctuating population size on capital accumulation. Other cases of nontrivial population dynamics may be observed in models where agents allocate their resources between childbearing and consumption (e.g., [46]).

The idea of the present paper is to study a Solow-type model in which one of the main characteristics is the introduction of reproductive mechanism that prevents unbounded population growth in the long run. In particular, we assume that (i) population dynamics is described by a delayed logistic equation [7], which presents a constant carrying capacity and (ii) a time-to-build technology characterizes the productive sector. Namely, we introduce two different sources of time-delays: with regard to the first assumption, it implies that there exists a lag between the birth date and the recruitment in the labour force; with regard to the second one, it means that production occurs with a delay while new capital is installed (investment gestation lag). Both processes affect the capital accumulation path by means of production function.

It is interesting to notice that the theoretical question whether lags in productive activity induce cycles is a topic that dates back to early economists such as Jevons [8] and Kalecki [9], and the introduction of new mathematical tools for the study of functional differential equations (e.g., the influential book of Hassard et al. [10]) has revitalized this issue. Nonetheless, the large part of the literature is focused on investment lags (e.g., [1114]), and the role of other kinds of lags in economic growth models or the linkages between population dynamics and lags in productive sector has received little attention. Exceptions are the papers of Fanti and Manfredi [2] described before; Bianca and Guerrini [15], who embed the problem of population dynamics in a network structure; Fanti et al. [16] who study problems related to demographic transition and the emergence of low-fertility traps in a model in which a system of differential equations with distributed delays is introduced to describe the age distribution of the population; Guerrini and Sodini [17] who analyze the role of the assumption of a positive or a negative constant population growth rate in a model with a time-to-build technology; and Ballestra et al. [18] who consider a Kaleckian type model of business cycle where a negative effect of the capital stock increases disproportionally as the capital stock builds up.

In the present paper, two alternative hypotheses on capital depreciation are explored. In the first hypothesis, it is assumed that the productive capital (i.e., the capital that actually is used in the productive process) depreciates at a constant rate (e.g., [11]). In the second one, it the case in which depreciation affects directly the investments even if they have not yet created productive capital is explored. The second case represents a plausible assumption if we consider capital in a broad sense that includes intangible capitals such as new inventions, prototypes, and patents. It is worth noting that, differently by Hongliang and Wenzao [19], business cycles phenomena may be observed even in the second case.

The paper is organised as follows. In Section 2, the models are formally introduced. Section 3 is focused on the study of the first model specification. In Section 4, the second model is analyzed. In Section 5, the global properties of the models are investigated via numerical simulations. Section 5 concludes.

2. The Models

2.1. First Specification

We introduce a Solow [20] model with the following characteristics. We assume that at time identical and competitive firms produce a homogeneous good, , by combining capital and labour and , respectively, through the constant returns to scale Cobb-Douglas technology. New investments display a delay of period before they can be used for production (time-to-build technology). Thus, the evolution of capital accumulation is governed by the following equation: where is a positive parameter representing (exogenous) technological progress, measures the productivity of capital, is the exogenous constant saving rate, is the state value of at time , and is the constant rate of productive capital depreciation (in this specification, obsolescence only affects capital if and only if this last is used in a productive process).

We assume that population of workers evolves according to the delayed logistic equation introduced by Hutchinson (see Arino et al. [21] for an alternative formulation): where is the constant carrying capacity and is the state value of at time . Notice that the presence of the delayed variable captures the lag between the birth date and the recruitment in the labour force while defines a limit to population growth. Other specifications (see [16]) that use delayed differential equations are mostly concerned with the description age-specific fertility and mortality rates.

Setting , we have

Hence, the model is described by

2.2. Second Specification

The second model differs from the first one in the fact that obsolescence affects capital regardless of its utilization in the productive process. Thus, (4) is replaced by the following:

Setting , we obtain

As a result, the model is now represented by

It is simple to verify that systems (4) and (7) have the same (nontrivial) equilibria. By setting and , and for all , we find that there exists a unique nontrivial equilibrium , where Notice that because the population dynamics is bounded from above and the level of technological progress is fixed, in the present work, differently from Guerrini and Sodini [17], a balanced growth path is not a feasible solution and identifies the stationary solution of the model, for which .

3. Local Analysis of System (4)

In order to study the local properties of the system around nontrivial equilibrium, we linearize system (4) at . This gives The characteristic equation can be derived from where is the identity matrix. A direct calculation shows that the above equation can be rewritten as where

By putting in (11), we obtain . We derive that the two roots of this equation are negative. Hence, the equilibrium is stable in case there is no delay. As increases, the stability of the equilibrium point will change when (11) under consideration has zero or a pair of purely imaginary eigenvalues. The former occurs when , and this is not possible. The latter deals with the existence of a root for (11). This means we need to investigate when and/or . Without loss of generality, since the complex roots of (11) appear as complex conjugate pairs, we assume that .

Lemma 1. Equation (resp., with (resp., ), , has a pair of purely imaginary roots (resp., ), where

Proof. Consider ; that is, . Separating real and imaginary parts of this equation, we obtain From in (14), and and being both positive, it follows that and . We also obtain a sequence of the critical values of . Next, suppose ; that is, . Then which lead to and the existence of . This concludes the proof.

We easily obtain the following result.

Proposition 2. (1) If , then characteristic equation (11) has a pair of purely imaginary roots at , .
(7) If , then characteristic equation (11) has a multiple root with the multiplicity of two.

Remark 3. When , the system (4) is a degenerated case and it is difficult to determine the crossing direction of the characteristic roots through the imaginary axis. Moreover, the criteria of stability switches fail to analyze the stability switches of system (4).

Henceforth, we assume , so that (11) has no repeated roots.

Lemma 4. For , , , , are simple roots of (11) with

Proof. Both and are simple. If we suppose, by contradiction, that, for example, is a repeated root, then and lead to a contradiction. Let be the branch of characteristic roots of (11) such that and . Taking the derivative of with respect to in (11), it follows that Then, we get Similarly for , the statement holds.

Therefore, a pair of pure imaginary roots will cross the imaginary axis from left to right as increases. Furthermore, this also yields to the existence of a Hopf bifurcation at the equilibrium when . Using this last lemma and the previous analysis about the existence of purely imaginary roots of (11), we can state the following theorem.

Theorem 5. Let , be defined as in (13), and let , where , .(1)The equilibrium point of (4) is locally asymptotically stable for and unstable for .(2)System (4) undergoes a Hopf bifurcation at the equilibrium when , .

4. Local Analysis of System (7)

In this section, we consider the model described by system (7). It is known that the modification of the Zak model [11] with the assumption that capital obsolescence affects the present capital makes the stationary equilibrium globally asymptotically stable for any value of time-delay (no Hopf bifurcation may occur) (see [19]). We will see that the introduction of population dynamics drastically changes the results.

As in the previous model, in order to study the local dynamics, we linearize system (7) at . We have The associated characteristic equation of system (19) is and takes the form where When , all roots of (21) are negative, so that the system is stable. We will let vary and investigate possible stability switches and bifurcations. For to become unstable, characteristic roots have to cross the imaginary axis to the right when increases. Let be a purely imaginary root of (21). Then, it satisfies and/or . Let . This can be rewritten as the following two equations: which imply Therefore, has no purely imaginary roots. Noticing that , with defined as in (12), it follows that has a unique pair of simple purely imaginary roots at a sequence of critical values , where and are defined by (13). Let denote the roots of (21) near satisfying and . Then, the following transversality condition holds and so the root crosses the imaginary axis from left to right (at ) as increases. Since is locally asymptotically stable when , then it becomes unstable at the smallest value of for which an imaginary root exists. Thus, we can get the following results.

Theorem 6. Let ,  , be defined as in (13), where .(1)The equilibrium point of (7) is locally asymptotically stable for and unstable for .(2)System (7) undergoes a Hopf bifurcation at the equilibrium when for .

Remark 7. Notice that bifurcation value of both the models is the same if .

5. Numerical Simulations

In order to understand the dynamical properties of the model, we consider a numerical specification and let vary. In particular, we set For this parameter specification and from Theorem 5, we have . Thus, the bifurcation values for the two models are the same and we have verified by means of several numerical experiments that the associated dynamics look very similar. Therefore, we focus on the simulations for model 1. Figure 1 shows the evolution of long run dynamics when is varied. It is interesting to note that after bifurcation, differently from Guerrini and Sodini [17], both the state variables oscillate permanently along the unstable equilibrium. If is increased, the enlargement of the limit cycle induces larger and larger oscillations. However, by means of several numerical experiments, it seems that only nonchaotic dynamics arise.

fig1
Figure 1: (a) Time evolution of size capital per worker (; (b) time evolution of population (; (c) time evolution of capital per worker (; and (d) time evolution of population (.

6. Conclusions

In this paper, we have analyzed the dynamics in Solow-type model with investment lags and nonstationary but bounded population. We have shown that the interaction between the population dynamics and time-to-build technology may be an engine of cyclical behaviour of capital accumulation. Formally, by applying the techniques developed by Hassard et al. [10] for delayed differential equations, we have proved that a Hopf bifurcation occurs once lag passes through a critical value and a family of periodic orbits bifurcates from the stationary equilibrium. Numerical simulations confirm the existence of oscillating dynamics in the demoeconomic variables. More complex structures of time-delays and microeconomic foundation of the model are left for future research.

Acknowledgment

The authors would like to thank the referees for the careful review and the valuable comments. Mauro Sodini acknowledges that this work has been performed within the activity of the PRIN Project “Local Interactions and Global Dynamics in Economics and Finance: Models and Tools,” MIUR, Italy.

References

  1. L. Guerrini, “The Solow-Swan model with a bounded population growth rate,” Journal of Mathematical Economics, vol. 42, no. 1, pp. 14–21, 2006. View at Publisher · View at Google Scholar · View at Zentralblatt MATH · View at Scopus
  2. L. Fanti and P. Manfredi, “The Solow’s model with endogenous population: a neoclassical growth cycle model,” Journal of Economic Development, vol. 28, no. 2, pp. 103–115, 2003.
  3. F. Fabião and M. J. Borges, “Existence of periodic solutions for a modified growth solow model,” in Proceedings of the 36th International Conference “Applications of Mathematics in Engineering and Economics” (AMEE '10), pp. 97–106, June 2010. View at Publisher · View at Google Scholar · View at Scopus
  4. J. Benhabib and K. Nishimura, “Endogenous fluctuations in the Barro-Becker theory of fertility,” in DemographicChange and Economic Development, A. Wenig and K. F. Zimmermann, Eds., pp. 29–41, Springer, Berlin, Germany, 1989.
  5. R. H. Day, K. Kim, and D. Macunovich, “Complex demoeconomic dynamics,” Journal of Population Economics, vol. 2, no. 2, pp. 139–159, 1989. View at Publisher · View at Google Scholar · View at Scopus
  6. G. Feichtinger and E. J. Dockner, “Capital accumulation, endogenous population growth, and Easterlin cycles,” Journal of Population Economics, vol. 3, no. 2, pp. 73–87, 1990. View at Publisher · View at Google Scholar · View at Scopus
  7. G. E. Hutchinson, “Circular causal systems in ecology,” Annals of the New York Academy of Sciences, vol. 50, no. 4, pp. 221–246, 1948. View at Publisher · View at Google Scholar · View at Scopus
  8. W. S. Jevons, 1911, The theory of Political Economy, 4th Ed. First published in 1871, Second, enlarged Edition in 1879, Macmillan, London, UK, 1871.
  9. M. Kalecki, “A macroeconomic theory of business cycles,” Econometrica, vol. 3, no. 3, pp. 327–344, 1935. View at Publisher · View at Google Scholar
  10. B. Hassard, D. Kazarino, and Y. Wan, Theory and Application of Hopf Bifurcation, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, 1981.
  11. P. J. Zak, “Kaleckian lags in general equilibrium,” Review of Political Economy, vol. 11, pp. 321–330, 1999.
  12. P. K. Asea and P. J. Zak, “Time-to-build and cycles,” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, vol. 23, no. 8, pp. 1155–1175, 1999. View at Publisher · View at Google Scholar · View at Scopus
  13. A. Krawiec and M. Szydłowski, “A note on Kaleckian lags in the Solow model,” Review of Political Economy, vol. 16, no. 4, pp. 501–506, 2004. View at Publisher · View at Google Scholar · View at Scopus
  14. M. Szydłowski, “Time to build in dynamics of economic models II: models of economic growth,” Chaos, Solitons and Fractals, vol. 18, no. 2, pp. 355–364, 2003. View at Publisher · View at Google Scholar · View at Zentralblatt MATH · View at Scopus
  15. C. Bianca and L. Guerrini, “On the Dalgaard-Strulik model with logistic population growth rate and delayed-carrying capacity,” Acta Applicandae Mathematicae, 2013. View at Publisher · View at Google Scholar
  16. L. Fanti, M. Iannelli, and P. Manfredi, “Neoclassical growth with endogenous age distribution. Poverty vs low-fertility traps as steady states of demographic transitions,” Journal of Population Economics, vol. 26, no. 4, pp. 1457–1484, 2013.
  17. L. Guerrini and M. Sodini, “Dynamic properties of the Solow model with increasing or decreasing population and time-to-build technology,” Abstract and Applied Analysis, 2013.
  18. L. V. Ballestra, L. Guerrini, and G. Pacelli, “Stability switches and Hopf bifurcation in a Kaleckian model of business cycle,” Abstract and Applied Analysis, vol. 2013, Article ID 689372, 8 pages, 2013. View at Publisher · View at Google Scholar
  19. Z. Hongliang and H. Wenzao, “Inada conditions and global dynamic analysis of basic growth models with time delays,” in Stochastic Economic Dynamics, B. S. Jensen and T. Palokangas, Eds., pp. 229–246, Copenhagen Business School Press, Copenhagen, Denmark, 2007.
  20. R. M. Solow, “A contribution to the theory of economic growth,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 70, pp. 65–94, 1956. View at Publisher · View at Google Scholar
  21. J. Arino, L. Wang, and G. S. K. Wolkowicz, “An alternative formulation for a delayed logistic equation,” Journal of Theoretical Biology, vol. 241, no. 1, pp. 109–119, 2006. View at Publisher · View at Google Scholar · View at Scopus