Abstract

We build a multiassets heterogeneous agents model with fundamentalists and chartists, who make investment decisions by maximizing the constant relative risk aversion utility function. We verify that the model can reproduce the main stylized facts in real markets, such as fat-tailed return distribution and long-term memory in volatility. Based on the calibrated model, we study the impacts of the key strategies’ parameters on investors’ wealth shares. We find that, as chartists’ exponential moving average periods increase, their wealth shares also show an increasing trend. This means that higher memory length can help to improve their wealth shares. This effect saturates when the exponential moving average periods are sufficiently long. On the other hand, the mean reversion parameter has no obvious impacts on wealth shares of either type of traders. It suggests that no matter whether fundamentalists take moderate strategy or aggressive strategy on the mistake of stock prices, it will have no different impact on their wealth shares in the long run.

1. Introduction

Compared with traditional economic modeling, agent-based modeling is more flexible in terms of characterizing the individual heterogeneity and population dynamics. This advantage is beneficial in researching on the survivability of different types of investors, namely, market selection.

Previously, the related studies on market selection and wealth share distribution concentrated mainly on the impact of prediction accuracy, risk-aversion level, learning process, and noise trading. Blume and Easley [1] associated market selection with the first-principle of welfare economics and discovered that, in complete market under Pareto optimum allocation, the survival and disappearance of investors depend on the accuracy of their forecasts. Similarly, Fedyk et al. [2] studied the multiasset economy situation and found that, compared with rational investors, unsophisticated investors could suffer severe loss in the long run, and even their predication deviations seem a priori small. Barucci and Casna [3] also found that, under the mean reverting environment, investors who have inaccuracy predictions cannot survive.

Conversely, Chen and Huang [4, 5] compared the influence of forecasting accuracy and risk preference for investors’ long-term survival, based on a multiassets agent-based artificial stock market. They put forward that the risk preference was the determinant and showed that the wealth of the investors who adopted logarithmic utility function could be dominated in the long run. In respect of learning evolution, LeBaron [6] focused on investors’ learning on the gain level, which is the weight level for the last step’s forecast error in their price forecast rules. This study showed the stylized facts of the market, analyzed the wealth evolution between different strategic investors, and demonstrated their influence on the market instability. Amir et al. [7] identified the adaptive portfolio strategies which could allow investors to survive under the frame of game theory. From the perspective of noise trading, several researchers used the agent-based modeling method to analyze the survival problem in the long run by comparing the specialists and the noise traders and the noise traders and BSV investors, respectively [810]. Zhao [11] studied the survival boundary conditions of different irrational investors by utilizing the market utility maximization rather than the individual utility maximization.

In the field of heterogeneous agents, fundamentalist/chartist modeling is a very important frame. For instance, Chiarella and He [12], Chiarella et al. [13], Anufriev and Dindo [14], Yuan and Fu [15], and Zou et al. [16] have mainly focused on the price equilibrium and system stability. This paper, however, focuses on the strategies parameters’ impacts on investors’ long-term wealth share, including fundamentalists’ mean reversion parameters and chartists’ exponential moving average periods under the fundamentalist/chartist modeling frame.

2. Heterogeneous Agent Model

For generality, this paper extends to multiassets case based on the Constant Relative Risk Aversion (CRRA) heterogeneous agent model which was proposed by Chiarella et al. [13]. The setting of the model is as follows.

2.1. The Market

This paper proposes a discrete-time model with risky assets and one risk-free asset in the financial market. The risk-free interest rate is constant. There are two types of strategic agents, fundamentalists and chartists, and a Walrasian auctioneer.

Consider risky asset . Under the assumption of traditional financial economics, investors have homogeneous rational expectations to the return of asset , and the fundamental price of asset can be derived from the “no-arbitrage” equation The fundamental long-run solution is given by where , , and denote the price, the fundamental value, and the dividend yield, respectively. In particular, if the dividend process is described by one can obtain where denotes the dividend growth rate of asset . Then one can easily obtain that the fundamental values evolve over time according to and that the capital return is given by where denotes the dividend growth rate of asset . In the following section we will introduce heterogeneity into the model. We assume agents have heterogeneous, time-varying beliefs about the first and second moment of capital returns, but for simplicity, they are assumed to share the same beliefs about dividend returns.

2.2. The Demand Function

Each agent is assumed to maximize the CRRA (power) utility function to allocate their wealth as follows: where represents the wealth and the parameter represents the relative risk aversion coefficient. We choose the CRRA utility function because this assumption is quite realistic. The experiment results of Levy et al. [17] support the decreasing absolute risk aversion (DARA). In other words, investor’s risk aversion declines with the increase of wealth, which is consistent with the CRRA (power) utility function. In addition, Campbell and Viceira [18] pointed out that relative risk aversion cannot depend strongly on wealth in the long-run behavior of the economy.

This paper extends the solution proposed by Chiarella and He [12] to the multiassets case and derives investors’ demand function. At time , the optimal wealth proportion to be invested in the risky asset is determined by maximizing the expected utility of wealth at , as given by To solve this, one needs to work out the evolution of .

Assume that the wealth follows a continuous time stochastic differential equation where is a Wiener process. Let be an invertible differentiable function with the inverse function . Following Ito’s lemma, which can be written as where Discretizing (11) using the Euler formula, one obtains the following approximation: It follows that Unitizing the time in (15), we have Substituting (12) into (17), one gets This is the evolution of .

Let where is the return of asset , is the standard deviation of the return of asset , and is an process.

Meanwhile, we assume that a trader’s wealth change equals to the sum of the return of the risk-free asset and the returns of risky assets; that is, where is the wealth proportion invested in asset at time .

Substituting (19) into (20), we have which can be written as where with Substituting (23) into (18), we have Thus the first order condition of the problem (8) leads to the following optimal solution: where represents the vector of the expected excess return on risky assets and represents the covariance matrix of the expected return on risky assets. Then we can get the investor’s position demand for all assets as follows: where , , and denote the price vector, the vector of the demand for asset position, and the division of the element as opposed to the vector, respectively. It can be seen that although the optimal investment proportion of an investor’s wealth to be invested in the risky asset is independent of wealth, its optimal position demand is proportional to wealth.

2.3. Heterogeneous Expectations

The heterogeneous beliefs of fundamentalists and chartists are reflected in the expected return as well as the expected variance. We assume that the same type of investors predicts all risky assets in the same way.

2.3.1. Fundamentalists

Assume that fundamentalists (denoted by ) know the fundamental value of assets. These investors believe that the price will move back to the fundamental value when the market price deviates from fundamental value. Therefore their expected price change is

Fundamentalists’ expected price is the sum of the change of the fundamental value and an adjustment item. The adjustment item is proportional to the deviation between current asset price and the fundamental value. The coefficient indicates the speed returning to the fundamental value, and we call it mean reversion coefficient. In addition, to simplify, we assume that the two types of investors have the same expectation to dividend return; that is, Thus, fundamentalist’s expected return for asset is

We further assume that fundamentalists use the exponential moving average of expected return deviation to determine the expected return variance. To certain extent, it reflects the adaptability; that is, where stands for the period length of the exponential moving average. The larger is , the smaller is . It shows that the longer is the moving average period, the smaller is the weight of the latest deviation. Thus the latest expected deviation has the smaller influence on the expected variance. Furthermore, this paper assumes that investors’ expected correlations between assets are ( , denotes the assets), which vary with different investors, but do not change with time. Hence, the covariance matrix of the expected return is

2.3.2. Chartists

Chartists do not know the fundamental value of the assets. They use the past price series to infer the movement of future prices. Therefore, chartists can be regarded as a kind of adaptive investors. This paper assumes that the first moment and the second moment of the expected return are adaptable for chartists; that is, both the expected return and its variance are obtained by using the exponential moving average. The expected price change of chartists is where presents the period length of the exponential moving average. Chartists have the same expected dividend yield as fundamentalists, whose expected return for asset is For chartists, the covariance matrix of the expected return is similar to that of fundamentalists.

2.4. Market Clearing

This model achieves market clearing through the equilibrium between supply and demand as where represents the investors, represents the number of fundamentalists, is the total number of investors, is the number of chartists, and is the number of outstanding stocks in the market. The equation indicates that the sum of risky asset holdings by all traders is equal to at any time , which is achieved by adjusting the equilibrium price repeatedly.

2.5. Wealth Shares

After the market price is determined through the clearing mechanism, the wealth of investor is also determined as follows: At this moment, the total wealth of all investors, the fundamentalists, and the chartists in the market is where is the number of investors, is the number of fundamentalists, is the number of chartists, is the total wealth of fundamentalists, and is the total wealth of chartists. Accordingly, investor ’s wealth share, all fundamentalists’ wealth share, and chartists’ wealth share in the market are defined as follows: By studying the relative wealth share rather than the absolute wealth amount, we can get to the wealth evolution of different types of investors more intuitively.

3. Simulation Results

To reflect the randomness of the dividend process, we revised the dividend process in the following agent-based experiments: Then we can obtain the fundamental value of the asset as follows: where and represents standard deviation dividend growth rates.

3.1. Reproducing Stylized Facts

Table 1 lists the parameters for the benchmark model. In this paper, we use three risky stocks as examples to calibrate this model and the parameters of all stocks are setting consistently. The fundamental value of each stock is setting to 10, each investor’s initial wealth is 10, so that his total initial wealth is 40. In addition, short selling is permitted in the model. The total number of investors is 40, including 20 fundamentalists and 20 chartists. One step in this model can be seen as one week in reality. Every experiment runs 1000 periods, corresponding to 20 years in reality.

The risk-free interest rate is 0.0012, corresponding to the annual interest rate which is about 6%. The dividend growth rate is 0.001, corresponding to the annual growth rate which is about 5%. The initial dividend is 0.002. Many studies suggest that the relative risk aversion is in the range from 2 to 4. In this paper, we set it to 3. To reflect the heterogeneity of the investors, the exponential moving average periods, fundamentalists’ mean reversion parameter, and the expected correlation coefficients between assets are randomly selected in a certain range by every trader at the beginning of the experiment, which are kept unchanged during the remaining experiment time. For example, the correlation coefficients between stocks are selected randomly in the range , which is consistent with real stock market (Ochiai and Nacher [19] show that the correlations between DJIA and Nikkei 225 roughly fluctuate within ).

It is easily understood that although stocks have the same parameters, due to the randomness of the dividend process and the different imbalances of supply and demand, the price evolutions of different stocks are not the same, and they can even be opposite.

Considering that our model is a growth model, in which the dividend growth rate is positive, if we compare one day to one time step, then the dividend growth rate will be so small that the model accuracy could be lost. Thus, in this paper, we use weekly closing prices of the S&P 500 index from December 30, 1991, to March 7, 2011, as the calibration series and compare it with the simulated price series in both the descriptive statistics and the stylized facts.

Figure 1 shows the evolution of stock prices. The bottom right plot is for the S&P 500 index. Table 2 shows the descriptive statistics of the three simulated stock prices and the S&P 500 prices. We can find that these properties of simulated prices are very similar with those of S&P 500 index.

Here we test the stylized facts of our model. Figures 2, 3, 4, 5, and 6 display the stylized facts of S&P 500, stock 1, stock 2, and stock 3. Figure 2 shows the probability density in the semilogarithmic axis, where the red line is normal fitted curve. We can find that both S&P 500 returns and the simulated stocks returns show the fat-tailed distribution. Figures 36 compare the autocorrelation functions of the return rate. In each plot, the black line shows the autocorrelation function of the original returns, and the red line is the autocorrelation of the absolute returns. From these autocorrelation plots, we can find that the original returns have no autocorrelations, whereas the absolute returns show significant long-term autocorrelations. In addition, the Hurst indexes for the absolute returns of three simulated stocks are 0.6993, 0.7585, and 0.6817, respectively, which confirm the property of long-term autocorrelation as in real markets [20]. We find that all three stocks show similar characteristics as S&P 500.

We conclude that our model is able to reproduce the main stylized facts of real stocks and stock indexes, including the fat-tailed distribution of returns, the absence of long-memory in the returns, and the strong long-term correlations in the absolute returns. It indicates that our model has captured some key ingredients of the microstructure of real financial markets.

3.2. Wealth Share Analysis

Investors’ beliefs play an important role in making investment decisions. Therefore, it is essential to analyze the key parameters that determine investor’s beliefs and focus on these parameters’ impacts on investors’ wealth accumulation. The model has two key parameters, including fundamentalists’ mean reversion parameters and chartists’ exponential moving average periods .

In order to analyze the two parameters’ impacts on two types of investors’ wealth shares, this paper divides the mean reversion parameter values into four intervals: , , , and . Fundamentalists’ mean reversion parameters value is randomly selected in the specific interval. We also take 9 different values for the chartists, that is, 1, 2, 3, 4, 5, 10, 20, 50, and 80, which correspond to 9 different weights of the latest price information, that is, 0.6321, 0.3935, 0.2835, 0.2212, 0.1813, 0.0952, 0.0488, 0.0198, and 0.0124. This results in 36 different parameters combinations. In order to keep the conclusion robust, this paper selects five different random seeds for each combination to conduct five experiments, and then average investors’ wealth shares of these five experiments. Thus, we run a total of 180 experiments. We focus on the aggregate wealth of the same type of traders. Figures 7, 8, 9, and 10 show investors’ wealth share for 4 different intervals of . In every figure, each bar corresponds to the average wealth share at the end of experiments when exponential moving average period is given a specific value.

We can see that no matter what kinds of parameters’ portfolios are chosen, the two types of investors coexist in the long term. Chartists’ wealth shares fall into the range of 0.3–0.5, and the corresponding fundamentalists’ wealth shares locate between 0.7 and 0.5. Meanwhile, different portfolios do have different distributions of wealth. Obviously, no matter is at which intervals, with the exponential moving average periods increasing, chartists’ wealth shares also show an increasing trend, indicating that a higher memory length will help chartists form more accurate expectations, thus increasing their wealth shares. However, this trend becomes less obvious when exponential moving average periods are high enough, such as is 20, 50, 80. This is because chartists’ return expectations only have very small weight on the latest price information (namely, 0.0488, 0.0198, and 0.0124), and more than 95% of the weights are given to the past pricing information. Hence, the growth trend of wealth share is no longer obvious when the exponential moving average period is sufficiently long.

In addition, the value of mean reversion coefficient has no significant impacts on the wealth share of the two types of investors. It suggests that the aggressiveness of fundamentalists’ strategies on the mistake of stock prices, be they moderate (when is small) or aggressive (when is large), has no impact on their wealth shares in the long run.

4. Conclusions

We have built a multiassets heterogeneous-agents model with fundamentalists and chartists. We verified that the model can reproduce the main stylized facts in real markets such as fat tails in the return distribution, absence of long-memory in returns, and long-term memory in the absolute returns. Based on the calibrated model, we studied the key strategies parameters’ impacts on investors’ wealth shares. We found that as chartists’ exponential moving average periods increase, their wealth shares also show an increasing trend. This means that higher memory length can help to improve their wealth shares. However when the exponential moving average periods are long enough, this trend is no longer obvious and no matter how long the memory is, wealth share of chartists will not be higher than fundamentalists’. That is, chartists’ wealth share will not be more than 0.5. This reflects that chartists can coexist with fundamentalists in stock markets, that is, at least accounting for about 30% of market wealth, although they cannot equally share the market wealth. On the other hand, the mean reversing parameter has no significant impacts on the wealth share of either type of traders. Therefore, no matter whether fundamentalists take moderate strategy or aggressive strategy on the mistake of stock prices, it has no different impacts on their wealth shares in the long run.

Conflict of Interests

The authors declare that there is no conflict of interests regarding the publication of this paper.

Acknowledgments

This research is partly supported by the NSFC (nos. 71131007 and 71271145), the Program for Changjiang Scholars and Innovative Research Team (no. IRT1028), and the Ph.D. Programs Foundation of Ministry of Education of China (no. 20110032110031).