Abstract

This paper investigates how the introduction of user fees and defensive expenditures changes the complex dynamics of a discrete-time model, which represents the interaction between visitors and environmental quality in an open-access protected-area (OAPA). To investigate this issue more deeply, we begin by studying in great detail the OAPA model, and then we introduce the user fee () and the defensive expenditures () specifically directed towards at the protection of the environmental resource. We observed that some values of can generate a chaotic regime from a stable dynamic of the OAPA model. Finally, to eliminate the chaotic regime, we design a controller by OGY method, assuming the user fee as a controller parameter.

1. Introduction

Empirical analysis has shown that tourists are willing to pay more for environmental management, if they believe that the money they pay will be allocated for biodiversity conservation and protected area management (see [1, 2]). Consequently, the funds for maintaining public goods can be increased by fees payed by visitors of the protected areas (PAs).

Several works in economic literature analyze the effects of ecological dynamics generated by economic activity and environmental defensive expenditures. In particular, [3, 4] analyze the stabilizing effect of ecological equilibria in an optimal control context in which ecological dynamics are represented by predator-prey equations.

More recently, economists, social and political scientists have started to develop and adapt chaos theory as a way of understanding human systems. Specifically, [5–10] have considered chaos theory as a way of understanding the complexity of phenomena associated with tourism.

In [11] a three-dimensional environmental defensive expenditures model with delay is considered. The model is based on the interactions among visitors , quality of ecosystem goods , and capital , intended as accommodation and entertainment facilities, in PA. The visitors’ fees are used partly as a defensive expenditure and partly to increase the capital stock.

Based on the continuous environmental model of [11], in this paper we analyze a discrete-time model with no capital stock and with no time delay. We aim at analyzing how the dynamics change when switching from an open-access protected area (OAPA) regime, where there are no services or facilities, to a PA regime with visitor fees used for environmental protection.

This paper is organized as follows. In Section 2, we present the discrete-time model that embodies the user fees and defensive expenditures. In Section 3, the dynamics of an open-access protected area, that is, without the user fee and defensive expenditures, is studied, including stable fixed points, periodic motions, bifurcations (flip-flop and Neimark-Sacker bifurcations), and chaos. Section 4 deals with the control of chaotic motion and the process of control is achieved an appropriate determination of user fees and defensive expenditures.

2. The Mathematical Model with User Fee and Defensive Expenditures

The model refers to a generic protected area and describes the interplay between two state variables: the size of the population of visitors of the protected area at time and an index measuring the quality of environmental resources of the protected area. The dynamic of is assumed to be described by the differential equation: According to such equation, the time evolution of depends on three factors: (i) represents the negative effect of the fee () that visitors have to pay to enter the protected area; (ii) is the negative effect due to congestion; (iii) ( is the parameter that presents attractiveness associated with high environmental quality) is the positive effect of environmental quality on visitors’ dynamics. , , and are strictly positive parameters.

The dynamic of the environmental quality index is assumed to be given by: where the time evolution of environmental quality is described by a logistic equation (see [12]). According to (2.2), visitors generate a negative impact on environmental quality (this effect is represented by ); however, visitors also generate a positive effect, in that, a share of the revenues deriving from the fees is used for environmental protection (this effect is represented by ). and are strictly positive parameters, while is a parameter satisfying .

Euler’s difference scheme for the continuous system (2.1)-(2.2) takes the form (see [13]): where denotes the time step. As , the discrete system converges to the continuous system. Roughly speaking, a discrete system can give rise to the same dynamics as a continuous system if the is small enough. However, it may generate qualitatively different dynamics if is large. In this sense, the discrete system with generalizes the corresponding continuous system. In the following, we first simplify the discretized system (2.3). Notice that a variable in continuous time can be written as in discrete time. Set ; then, given , the variable can be expressed as follows;. Thus the discretized dynamic system (2.3) can be written as:

The length of each period is equal to . For notational convenience, replacing with and posing , , , , , and we obtain the following discrete-time system: where and represent, respectively, the size of the population of visitors and the value of the quality index at time ; the parameters , , , , , and have the same meaning of the corresponding parameters , , , , , and , in the system (2.3).

3. The Dynamic Behavior of an Open-Access PA Model

In this section, we analyze the dynamics of our model under the assumption of free-access in the protected area; in this context, visitors do not have to pay a fee to visit the area, and system (2.5) becomes

To compute the fixed points of (3.1), we have to solve the nonlinear system of equations:

Proposition 3.1. The system (3.1) always present two fixed points:(a); (b).

Now we study the stability of these fixed points. The local stability of a fixed point (it denotes or ) is determined by the modules of the eigenvalues of the characteristic equation evaluated at the fixed point.

The Jacobian matrix of the system (3.1) evaluated at is given by where and . The characteristic equation of the Jacobian matrix can be written as where and . In order to study the moduli of the eigenvalues of the characteristic equation (3.4), we first give the following lemma, which can be easily proved.

Lemma 3.2. Let . Suppose that , andare two roots of. Then: (i) and sink if and only if and ;(ii) and or and saddle if and only if ;(iii) and source if and only if and ;(iv) and flip-flop bifurcation if and only if and ;(v) and are complex and Neimark-Sacker bifurcation if and only if and .

From Lemma 3.2, it follows the following.

Proposition 3.3. The fixed point is always unstable, while the fixed point , varying , can be a sink, a source, or a saddle see Figure 1.

Figure 1 shows the values of , , , defined in Lemma 3.2, as functions of the parameter .

We fix , , and , and assume that can vary. Smaller values of (see Figure 1) give rise to real eigenvalues, while higher values of it give rise to complex eigenvalues.

According to Lemma 3.2, when the parameter belongs to the interval (dash-dot line) we are in the situation described in point of Lemma 3.2; when , a flip-flop bifurcation occurs; when , we are in the context described in (solid line); at the value , a Neimark-Saker bifurcation takes place; finally, for , the fixed point becomes unstable.

Such results are illustrated in Figures 2 and 3, which show that some remarkable phenomena occur.

Figure 3(a) shows a strange attractor appearance posing . If the value of increases, we obtain the attractive fixed point showed in Figure 3(b): both variables of the dynamic system approach a unique fixed point independently from the initial state. The fixed point is characterized by the coordinates and . The eigenvalues of the Jacobian matrix evaluated at such point are with .

Continuing to increase the value of , a Neimark-Sacker bifurcation takes place. For the parameter value , the fixed point has coordinates and , and the associated pair of complex conjugate eigenvalues are with ; this shows that the eigenvalues belong to the unit circle, and the stability properties of the equilibrium change through a Neimark-Sacker bifurcation. Figure 3(c) illustrates the phase plot corresponding to the bifurcation value of .

Continuing to increase the value of , we see what happens for . The coordinates of the fixed point are and , and the associated eigenvalues are . The modulus of the complex conjugate eigenvalues is , and so we can conclude that the fixed point becomes unstable, and an invariant closed curve arises around such point, which is shown in Figure 3(d).

As is further increased, a strange attractor is generated by successive stretching and folding. The fixed point has coordinates and , and the corresponding eigenvalues are , with . The strange attractor is generated by the breaking of the invariant circles and the appearance of twelve chaotic (not shown in this figure) regions changes as they are linked into a single-chaotic attractor.

4. Controlling through Ξ² by OGY Method

In the preceding section we showed that, according to other works in the literature (see [14, 15]) environmental defensive expenditures may generate chaotic behavior which, in turn, may jeopardize environmental sustainability of economic activity. In this section, we show how chaos can be ruled out from the dynamics of our model by an appropriate choice of the visitors fee and of the defensive expenditure . We are interested in modifying the dynamic behavior of the model by introducing the visitors fee and the defensive expenditure . As it was shown in Figure 2, at the value , the model presents a stable fixed point. Figure 4 shows the bifurcation diagram of the system (2.5), where parameter varies in the interval and parameter is posed equal to 0.2. We can obtain both stable dynamics and chaotic dynamics. In fact, starting from a stable fixed point of the system, for values of , the system (2.5) admits a stable fixed point, while for chaotic dynamic occurs.

In this section, we describe a method that allows to stabilize this chaotic dynamic. In order to achieve this goal, the so-called OGY method (see [16]) is used.

The OGY method was successfully used in several studies, both in economics and physics (see e.g., [17, 18]). As it is summarized in [18–20], the OGY method is based on the following assumptions:(a1)a chaotic solution of a nonlinear dynamic system may have even an infinite number of unstable periodic orbits;(a2)in a neighborhood of a periodic solution; the evolution of the system can be approximated by an appropriate local linearization of the equation of motion;(a3)small perturbations of the parameter of the system can shift the chaotic orbit toward the so-called stable manifold of the chosen periodic orbit;(a4)The points belonging to the stable manifold approach the periodic solution in the course of time;our goal is to find a β€œgood” way to approach the periodic unstable orbit by proper changes of the parameter if the starting point is in a neighbourhood of the periodic unstable orbit.Let us assume that the model can be described as where , is real parameter, ;(a5)Suppose that we have a fixed point corresponding to a fixed parameter value such that and such fixed point is unstable;(a6)assume that the Jacobian matrix has two eigenvalues satisfying.

Then it follows from that, starting sufficiently close to and , we can approximate the right-hand side of (2.5) by the first-degree terms of its Taylor expansion around and Then, by , modifying we try to shift the chaotic orbit toward a stable manifold.

Thanks to the OGY method, the goal of approaching a stable manifold may be achieved as follows. Let and be close enough to and as required in . Then, the next point of the orbit is determined by (4.1): Our aim is to determine , that is, how to control the system that orbit approaches the unstable fixed point.

From the above results we get the following theorem.

Theorem 4.1. Under the assumptions –, there is a value for such that trajectory of the recurrence map (4.1) is shifted towards the stable manifold.

We fix the parameters , , , ,, and ; in such context the system exhibits a chaotic attractor. We take as the control parameter which allows for external adjustment but is restricted to lie in a small interval , , around the nominal value . The system becomes

Following [21], we consider the stabilization of the unstable period one orbit . The map (4.4) can be approximated in the neighborhood of the fixed point by the following linear map: where are the Jacobian matrixes with respect to the control state variable and to the control parameter . The partial derivatives are evaluated at the nominal value and at . In our case we get Next, we check whether the system is controllable. A controllable system is one for which a matrix can be found such that has any desired eigenvalues. This is possible if , where is the dimension of the state space, and In our case it follows that which obviously has rank 2, and so we are dealing with a controllable system. If we assume a linear feedback rule (control) for the parameter of the form: where , then the linearized map becomes that is, which shows that the fixed point will be stable provided that is that all its eigenvalues have modulus smaller than one. The eigenvalues and of the matrix are called the β€œregulator poles,” and the problem of placing these poles at the desired location by choosing with given is called the β€œpole-placement problem”. If the controllability matrix’ from (4.8) is of rank , in our case, then the pole-placement problem has a unique solution. This solution is given by where , and Here, are the coefficients of the characteristic polynomial of , that is are the coefficients of the desired characteristic polynomial of , that is From (4.13); we get that Since the map is nonlinear, the application of linear control theory will succeed only in a sufficiently small neighborhood around . Taking into account the maximum allowed deviation from the nominal control parameter and (4.10), we obtain that we are restricted to the following domain: This defines a slab of width and thus we activate the control (4.10) only for values of inside this slab, and choose to leave the control parameter at its nominal value when is outside the slab.

Any choice of regular poles inside the unit circle serves our purpose. There are many possible choices of the matrix . In particular, it is very reasonable to choose all the desired eigenvalues to be equal to zero, and in this way the target would be reached at least after periods, and therefore, a stable orbit is obtained out of the chaotic evolution of the dynamics.

In Figures 5(a) and 5(b), we show the time series of the chaotic trajectory starting from the point which we have chosen to control. In contrast, Figures 5(c) and 5(d) present the controlled orbit converging to the stabilized fixed point when the feedback matrix is chosen such that the eigenvalues of are . This implies that , and so . For this control strategy, we have also chosen .

5. Conclusion

In this paper we studied a discrete-time model that describes the interaction between visitors and the environment resource, in an open-access protected area (OAPA). It was shown that by varying the parameter that indicates the preferences of visitors with reference to the environmental quality, complex dynamics may occur (flip-flop bifurcation, Neimark-Sacker bifurcation, and chaotic dynamics). Furthermore, we analyzed the impact that user fees and environmental defensive choices can have on the OAPA dynamics when it presents an attractive fixed point. Finally, we have applied the OGY control technique (with user fee as control parameter) and we have shown that the aperiodic and complicated motion arising from the dynamics of the model can be easily controlled by small perturbations in their parameters and turned into a stable steady state.