Abstract

We formulate the thermodynamics of economic systems in terms of an arbitrary probability distribution for a conserved economic quantity. As in statistical physics, thermodynamic macroeconomic variables emerge as the mean value of microeconomic variables, and their determination is reduced to the computation of the partition function, starting from an arbitrary function. Explicit hypothetical examples are given which include linear and nonlinear economic systems as well as multiplicative systems such as those dominated by a Pareto law distribution. It is shown that the macroeconomic variables can be drastically changed by choosing the microeconomic variables in an appropriate manner. We propose to use the formalism of phase transitions to study severe changes of macroeconomic variables.

1. Introduction

Thermodynamics is a phenomenological science that derives its concepts directly from observation and experiment. The laws of thermodynamics can be considered as axioms of a mathematical model, and the fact that they are based upon commonplace observations makes them tremendously powerful and generally valid. In particular, the interest of applying thermodynamics in a systematic manner to describe the behavior of economic and financial systems has a long history [1]. One of the difficulties of this approach is that it is necessary to identify a priori the economic variables that can be identified as thermodynamic variables, satisfying the laws of thermodynamics. The results of this identification are very often controversial. For instance, whereas in some studies money is considered as a well-defined thermodynamic variable, other analyses suggest that money is a completely irrelevant economic variable that, consequently, should not be used in any thermodynamic approach to economy [2]. Even the basic thermodynamic assumption that an economic system be in equilibrium has been the subject of numerous discussions. The concept of economic entropy presents also certain difficulties and different definitions can be formulated [3, 4]. Formal mappings between thermodynamic and economic variables can be formulated [5] which, however, leave the notion of entropy unclear and the range of models in which it holds undefined.

On the other hand, econophysics is a relatively new branch of physics [6] in which several methods of applied theory of probabilities, that have been used with excellent results in statistical physics, are implemented to solve problems in economics and finance. In our opinion, one of the most prominent founds is that certain economic variables can be considered as conserved and their distribution among the agents of an economic system are described by simple probability densities. In fact, it is currently well established that wealth distribution in many societies presents essentially two phases [715]. This means that the society can be differentiated in two disjoint populations with two different probability distributions. Various analysis of real economic data from several countries have shown that one phase possesses a Boltzmann-Gibbs (exponential) probability distribution that involves about 95% of individuals, mostly those with medium and low wealths, whereas the second phase, consisting of about 5% of individuals with highest wealths, shows a Pareto (power law) probability distribution. Similar results are found for the distribution of money and income.

In a recent review [16], the concepts of classical thermodynamics are shown to be applicable to economic systems and a consistent thermodynamic formulation of economics is presented, using the language of calculus and differential forms and the fundamentals of statistics. Moreover, it is shown that thermodynamic concepts like entropy, temperature, pressure, and volume can be related to economic concepts like production, effective costs, capital growth, and capital. Furthermore, a recent work [17] demonstrates in a plausible manner that statistical models based on exponential and power law distributions can be used to reproduce the distribution of money, wealth, and income in modern societies. Additionally, the dynamics of such statistical models was shown to be described as a stochastic Markov process so that the distribution function, which depends explicitly on time, satisfies the Fokker-Planck equation. In the present work, we propose a different approach in which the concepts of microeconomic and macroeconomic parameters are introduced by using the classical definition of partition functions. We propose to use the standard formulation of statistical thermodynamics in order to relate in a systematic and rigorous way the thermodynamic approach with the statistical properties of complex economic systems found in econophysics. We obtain as a result that the entire properties of economic systems can, in principle, be formulated and considered in the definition of a partition function from which all the thermodynamic properties of the system can be derived. It turns out that in certain systems, the macroeconomic variables can be manipulated in an arbitrary way by changing the values of specific microeconomic variables. Moreover, the drastic changes that occur at the level of the macroeconomic variables can be investigated by using the formalism of phase transitions.

This paper is organized as follows. In Section 2 we formulate the fundamentals of statistical thermodynamics in the case of an arbitrary conserved economic variable. In Section 3.1, we analyze the simplest case of an economic system for which the conserved variable depends linearly on the microeconomic parameters. More general situations are analyzed in Sections 3.2 and 3.3, where quadratic and multiplicative dependences of abstract parameters are considered. The partition function is analyzed in all the cases and possible interpretations are presented. In Section 4, we propose to associate drastic modifications of macroeconomic variables with the occurrence of phase transitions. Finally, Section 5 contains a summary and a discussion of our results.

2. Statistical Thermodynamics

Consider a hypothetical economic system in equilibrium for which a quantity, say , is conserved. There is a reasonable number of arguments [18] which show that certain current economies can be considered as systems in equilibrium, and some quantities, like the total amount of money in the system, are conserved during certain periods of time. For the sake of concreteness, we will consider in this work that is the conserved money although our approach can be applied to any conserved quantity. Suppose that the system is composed of agents which compete to acquire a participation of . In real economic systems, the total number of agents is such a large number that for most applications the limit is appropriate. In a closed economic system, the equilibrium probability distribution (density function) of is given by the Boltzmann-Gibbs distribution , where is an effective temperature equal to the average amount of money per agent. The amount of money that an agent can earn depends on several additional parameters , which we call microeconomic parameters. Since the density function can be normalized to 1, we obtain [19] where is the partition function and represents the set of all microeconomic parameters. Here, we have introduced the notation to denote the possible set of macroeconomic parameters which can appear after the integration over the entire domain of definition of the microeconomic parameters .

Following the standard procedure of statistical thermodynamics [19], we introduce the concept of mean value for any function as These are the main concepts which are needed in statistical thermodynamics for the investigation of a system which depends on the temperature and macroscopic variables . Consider, for instance, the mean value of the money , and let us compute the total differential , The first term of this expression can be further manipulated by using the definition of the density function (1) in the form . Then, we obtain (recall that and, therefore, ) where the entropy and the “intensive” macroscopic variables are defined in the standard manner as Clearly, (4) represents the first law of thermodynamics. Since the definition of temperature and entropy are in accordance with the concepts of statistical mechanics, the remaining laws of thermodynamics are also valid. Similar results can be obtained for any quantity that can be shown to be conserved in an economic system. This reflects the fact that different thermodynamic potentials can be used to describe the same thermodynamic system.

It is useful to calculate explicitly the entropy by using the definition (1) in the form . The result can be cast in the form so that This means that the entire information about the thermodynamic properties of the system is contained in the expression for the “free money” which, in turn, is completely determined by the partition function . In statistical physics, this procedure is still used, with excellent results, to investigate the properties of thermodynamic systems. We propose to use a similar approach in econophysics. In fact, to investigate a model for an economic system one only needs to formulate the explicit dependence of any conserved quantity, say money , in terms of the microeconomic parameters . From , one calculates the partition function and the free money which contains all the thermodynamic information about the economic system.

As mentioned in Section 1, the concept of economic entropy still presents certain difficulties [3, 4]. In the statistical approach formulated here, it can be considered as a measure of the irrevocable degradation of the ability to perform an economic activity. In this sense, the value of the entropy depends entirely on the selected function . In the examples to be considered below, we will see that the entropy is a measure of the “price” to be payed to reach a positive change of the money's mean value. This interpretation is in agreement with the notion of entropy per agent [4]. In this case, the free money can be interpreted as an intrinsic money measure that characterizes the potential to deliver money to an external market through voluntary trade. For a different choice of , it should be possible to identify the mean value with the total capital of the economic system so that the entropy can be associated with the production function and the free money turns out to be the effective cost function [16].

In the next sections, we present several examples of hypothetical economic systems with relatively simple expressions for . In real economic systems, probably very complicated expressions for will appear for which analytical computations are not available. Nevertheless, the calculation of the above integrals for the partition function can always be performed by using numerical methods so that the corresponding thermodynamic properties of the system can be found qualitatively.

3. Hypothetical Economic Systems

The determination of the quantity in terms of the microeconomic parameters is a task that requires the knowledge of very specific conditions and relationships within a given economic system. The first step consists of identifying the microeconomic parameters which influences the capacity of an individual agent to compete for a share of the conserved quantity . Then, it is necessary to establish how this influence should be represented mathematically so that becomes a well-defined function of .

Another aspect that must be considered is the fact that in a realistic economic system not all agents are equivalent. For instance, an agent represented by an individual who works at a factory for a fixed yearly income would be considerably different from an agent represented by the firm to which the factory belongs. An important result of econophysics is that the Botzmann-Gibbs distribution is not affected by the specific characteristics of the agents involved in the economic model [7]. For the statistical thermodynamic approach, we are proposing in this work this means that we can decompose the quantity into classes , and different classes can be described by different functions of different sets of microeconomic parameters. The formalism of statistical thermodynamics allows us to consider, in principle, all possible economic configurations as far as is a well-defined function of .

In the following subsections, we will study several hypothetical economic systems in which is given as simple ordinary functions of the microeconomic parameters. We expect, however, that these simple examples will find some applications in the context of economic systems with sufficiently well-defined microeconomic parameters. Although the function can represent any conserved economic quantity, for the sake of concreteness, we will assume that it represents the money and from now on will be referred as to the money function.

3.1. Linear Systems

The simplest model corresponds to the case const. Then, the partition function (1) is given by where , , represent the macroeconomic parameters. The calculation of the thermodynamic variables, according to (7), yields Furthermore, from the definition of free money , we conclude that ; that is, the mean value of money is a constant, as expected. This economic model is considerably simple. Each agent possesses the same amount of money , the entropy does not depend on the mean value of the money , and the state equations are and . The system is completely homogeneous in the sense that each agent starts with a given amount of money, , and ends up with the same amount. Probably, the only way to simulate such an economic system would be by demanding that agents do not interchange money; this is not a very realistic situation. Indeed, the fact that the entropy is a constant, that does not depend on the mean value of the money, allows us to renormalize the macroscopic parameters in such a way that , for each , so that the total entropy vanishes. In this case, from (9), we see that and the corresponding equations of state are compatible with the limit . This resembles the argumentation used in the description of the third law of thermodynamics. This observation indicates that a completely homogeneous economic system is not realizable as a consequence of the third law of thermodynamics.

Consider now the function where is a positive constant. The corresponding partition function can be written as The relevant thermodynamic variables follow from (6) and (7) as and the conservation law (4) becomes Moreover, comparing the above results with the definition of , it can be shown that , and so, the fundamental thermodynamic equation in the entropic representation [20] can be written as This expression relates all the extensive variables of the system, and it can be used to derive all the equations of state in a manner equivalent to that given in (13). Notice that in this case, the entropy is proportional to the temperature (mean value of money) so that an increase of the average money per agent is necessarily associated with an increase of entropy. This observation is in agreement with the second law of thermodynamics. Notice, furthermore, that in a limiting case, similar to that considered in the first example given above, it is possible to renormalize the macroeconomic parameters such that the last term of the fundamental equation (15) vanishes. Nevertheless, in order to reach the minimum value of the entropy, it is necessary to consider the limit . Again, we consider this result as an indication of the validity of the third law of thermodynamics.

In (11), we have chosen the interval for the integration along the variable . As a consequence the macroscopic variable vanishes from the final expression for the fundamental equation (15), and consequently, . However, it is also possible to consider the interval so that the macroscopic variables and reappear in the fundamental equation and can be used as extensive variables which enter the conservation law (4). In this and further examples, the limits of the interval are chosen in order to obtain analytical compact expressions and are not motivated by economic considerations. In a realistic economic system, the interval of integration will depend on the economic significance of the microeconomic parameter . The limits and will then contain all possible situations that can be influenced by . For the sake of simplicity, we choose in this work the former case in which the corresponding macroeconomic parameter does not enter the analysis.

It is interesting to analyze the most general linear system for which where are positive real constants. It is then straightforward to calculate the partition function and the relevant thermodynamic variables All the macroscopic parameters vanish, and the system depends only on the temperature. However, the total number of macroscopic parameters does enter the expression for the entropy so that to increase the mean value of the money by the amount , it is necessary to increase entropy by an amount ; both amounts are proportional to the total number of macroscopic parameters.

Another consequence of this analysis is that once the constants and are fixed, it is not possible to change the mean value of the money without changing the temperature of the system. This means that an isothermal positive change of is possible only by increasing the total amount of money in the system.

3.2. Nonlinear Systems

Consider the quadratic function which generates the partition function where we have considered the microeconomic parameter in the interval . The corresponding thermodynamic variables are which can be put together in the fundamental equation Again, we see that the effect of considering the extreme values of the parameter is that the corresponding macroscopic variable does not enter the expressions for the thermodynamic variables, and, consequently, the corresponding intensive thermodynamic variable vanishes. Furthermore, it is evident that the power of in the money function leads to a decrease of the mean value .

To investigate the general case, we consider the monomial functional dependence , with being an arbitrary real constant. A straightforward calculation leads to the following partition function and thermodynamic variables: and the intensive variables are given as in the previous case. It follows that in order for the mean value of the money to be positive. If , the mean value of the money decreases, whereas it increases for . In such a hypothetical system, a way to increase the amount of money per agent would be to identify the microeconomic parameter and apply the measures which are necessary for the money function to become , with .

If we consider a transition of an economic system from a state characterized by the parameter to a new state with parameter , maintaining the same temperature, the mean value of the money undergoes a change so that for a positive change, we must require that . Moreover, if we desire a positive change by an amount greater than the average money per agent (), we must demand that . Even if the initial state corresponds to a linear system , in which no increase of is possible, we can reach a state of greater mean value by demanding that . Of course, for a positive change of the “price” to be payed will result in an increase of entropy by an amount which is proportional to the coefficient .

We see this possibility as an advantage of our statistical approach. In fact, we start from an equilibrium state with a lower value of and end up in a state with a higher value of by choosing appropriately a particular microeconomic parameter. The positive change of the macroeconomic variable is induced by a change of a microeconomic parameter. Once the process is started, the system will naturally evolve into a state characterized by a higher value of . This natural evolution occurs because, as has been repeatedly shown in computer simulations [18], the final equilibrium state corresponds to a Boltzmann-Gibbs probability distribution, which is a basic component of the approach proposed in this work.

3.3. Multiplicative Systems

An interesting case follows from the money function . In fact, the partition function is given by where we have used , with . This expression is nothing more but the partition function (cumulative probability) of the Pareto distribution density which has been shown to correctly describe the distribution of money (and other conserved economic quantities) in the upper tail of the distribution, that is, for amounts greater than . A similar derivation of the Pareto law was recently performed in [21].

We now have the possibility to analyze the Pareto distribution in terms of macroeconomic parameters. The computation of the thermodynamic variables using (7) yields Notice that the intensive variable conjugate to the lower limit of Pareto's distribution appears with a different sign, when compared with the remaining intensive variables . As a consequence of this change of sign the conservation law is given as so that if we interpret, by analogy with physical systems, the intensive variables as “forces”, we can conclude that the “force” corresponding to Pareto's distribution is negative. Moreover, if from the above expressions and that of the free money , we calculate the mean value , we obtain The origin of the second term is clear, because we have chosen the money function as and is the minimum value of . The first term, however, is new and has the interesting property that it diverges as . This means that it is possible to increase arbitrarily the value of in the upper tail of the distribution of money, maintaining the values of and fixed, solely by fine tuning the value of the constant so that it takes the value of the average amount of money per agent . Perhaps this simple observation could be useful for the understanding of the monetary evolution that takes place in the upper class of the wealth distribution in certain economies.

Finally, we analyze the case of the money function which corresponds to the density distribution where , , and are constants. This expression is known in the literature as the Gamma distribution and has been used in econophysics to investigate models with multiplicative asset exchange [22]. A straightforward computation shows that the corresponding partition function can be cast in the form an expression which is essentially equivalent to the partition function (22) following from the monomial function discussed in Section 3.2. In particular, in the limit the two partition functions coincide. Strong differences can appear near the points, where the function (31) diverges. This occurs when , which we should avoid in accordance with the third law of thermodynamics, and at the poles of the Gamma function, that is, for . The last possibility, however, is not necessarily in disagreement with the third law of thermodynamics since at the poles the temperature can be made to tend to a constant positive value, .

It is not difficult to derive the thermodynamic variables for this case. The singular pole structure of the partition function leads to a peculiar behavior of the thermodynamic variables which deserve a more detailed and deeper analysis. Outside the poles, however, the thermodynamic behavior is essentially dictated by (23) which correspond to a Boltzmann-Gibbs distribution with a power law dependence for the money function. This result shows that from a macroeconomic point of view there is no essential difference between the Gamma law distribution and the Boltzmann-Gibbs distribution, as far as the value for the temperature does not correspond to a singular pole of the partition function of the Gamma distribution. This result explains in a simple manner why in concrete examples it is possible to mimic the results of an exponential distribution by choosing appropriately the additional parameters of the Gamma law distribution [23].

4. Phase Transitions

An important feature of many thermodynamic systems is their capability to exist in different phases with specific interior and exterior characteristics which can drastically change during a phase transition. The thermodynamic approach proposed in this work insinuates the possibility of considering the phase structure of economic systems and the conditions under which a particular economic system can undergo a phase transition. In this section, we will perform such an analysis for the hypothetical systems studied above.

Recall that a phase transition is usually associated with discontinuities or divergences in the thermodynamic variables or its derivatives. In particular, the behavior of the entropy function is used as a criterion for the analysis of phase transitions. Moreover, the heat capacity is an important thermodynamic variable which indicates the existence of second-order phase transitions.

From the results presented in the preceding sections one can show that the heat capacity for systems characterized by a monomial money function, , is constant, namely, , with for the limiting case const. Since the constant must be positive for the mean value to be positive, the temperature of such systems raises under an increase of “economic heat”, and vice versa. An inspection of the remaining thermodynamic variables shows that such systems cannot undergo a phase transition. An interesting additional result is that such hypothetical systems are stable. In fact, a positive heat capacity is usually interpreted in statistical mechanics as a condition of stability. Consequently, systems described by monomial money functions with are stable.

The situation is different in the case of multiplicative systems. For a system characterized by a Pareto law distribution, we obtain from (25) First, we notice that this heat capacity is positive, indicating that the system is stable. However, a phase transition occurs in the limit , where the heat capacity diverges. This is also the value for which the mean value of the money raises unlimitedly. This shows that a phase transition can be induced by choosing appropriately the parameter and the corresponding economic system undergoes a drastic change with agents possessing more and more money; however, this hypothetical process must end at some stage due to the natural boundary imposed by the fact that the total amount of money in the system is fixed and finite. During the phase transition, several thermodynamic variables diverge, and, consequently, the thermodynamic approach breaks down. As in ordinary thermodynamics, a different (nonequilibrium) approach is necessary to understand the details of the phase transition. This is beyond the scope of the present work.

In the case of a system with a Gamma law distribution and partition function given in (31), the phase structure is much more complex. The analytical results are rather cumbersome expressions that cannot be written in a compact form. A preliminary numerical analysis shows that near the poles of the partition function first-order and second-order phase transitions occur with two possible scenarios. The first one is similar to the phase transition of a system with a Pareto law distribution with the mean value increasing either exponentially or as , and , where the value of the constant depends on the kind of pole of the partition function. The second scenario is characterized by a rapid reduction of , tending exponentially to a fixed positive value which depends on the kind of pole. Unexpectedly, we also found divergences in the corresponding heat capacity which are not related to the poles of the partition function. A more deep analysis will be necessary to understand the complete phase structure of this specific multiplicative system.

5. Discussion and Conclusions

In this work, we propose to apply the standard methods of statistical thermodynamics in order to investigate the structure and behavior of economic systems. The starting point is an economic system in which a conserved quantity is present. In certain current economies, it has been shown that such quantities exist, the money being one of them. We have shown that to any conserved quantity it is possible to associate a function (the money function, for instance) from which all the thermodynamic variables and properties of the system can be derived. The money function depends on a set of microeconomic parameters which generate macroeconomic parameters at the level of the partition function. The thermodynamic variables depend on the macroeconomic parameters and satisfy the ordinary laws of thermodynamics.

Starting from simple money functions, we consider linear, nonlinear, and multiplicative systems as examples of hypothetical economic systems in which it is possible to apply our approach, obtaining analytical results. In all the cases, we computed the most relevant thermodynamic variables and analyzed their behavior. The results show that it is possible to manipulate the microeconomic parameters in order to control the output at the level of the macroeconomic parameters. We see this possibility as an advantage of our statistical approach. One can start from an equilibrium state with some given mean value for the money and raise its value by choosing appropriately a particular microeconomic parameter. Once the process is started, the system will naturally evolve into a state characterized by a greater value of . This natural evolution occurs because, as has been repeatedly shown in computer simulations [18], the final equilibrium state corresponds to a Boltzmann-Gibbs probability distribution, which is a basic component of the approach proposed in this work. This evolution, however, must be understood as in standard thermodynamics, that is, the evolution process must be quasistatic so that at each step the economic system is in equilibrium. A more realistic evolutionary model must take into account nonequilibrium states, a task that cannot be treated within the standard approach of statistical thermodynamics. It would be interesting to investigate if the existing generalizations of nonequilibrium thermodynamics can also be applied in the context of economic systems.

We propose to use the formalism of phase transitions to analyze the behavior of economic systems. The relatively simple examples studied in this work show that in fact, a phase transition can be associated to drastic changes of the mean value of the money. Economic crisis are usually accompanied by far-reaching modifications of some macroeconomic variables. It would be interesting to propose more sophisticated and realistic models for money functions and investigate their behavior during phase transitions. If a crisis could be understood this way, an appealing problem would be to explore the possibility of controlling its consequences. To investigate this problem, it will be necessary to explore and establish the economic meaning of the microeconomic variables by using an approach based upon concepts of standard economics. This remains an open question that could be the subject of further investigations.

In the context of systems with many constituents, thermodynamic interaction is an important concept which can completely modify the interior and exterior structure of the system. In physics, one can introduce thermodynamic interaction into a system by choosing appropriate potentials, because we understand the physical meaning of the Hamiltonian function. In our approach, the analogous of the Hamiltonian is the money function; we believe, however, that its economic significance, at least at the moment, is much more sophisticated. Therefore, we propose to use a different method to introduce thermodynamic interaction into an economic system. Recently, the theory of geometrothermodynamics [24] was formulated with the aim of describing thermodynamics in terms of geometric concepts. One of the results of this formalism is that thermodynamic interaction can be interpreted as the curvature of the equilibrium space. This has been shown to be true not only in the case of ordinary thermodynamic systems, like the ideal gas and the van der Waals gas [25, 26], but also in more exotic configurations like black holes [27]. This opens the possibility of introducing thermodynamic interaction by just modifying the curvature of the equilibrium space. In fact, it can be shown that all the hypothetical economic systems analyzed in this work have very simple equilibrium spaces for which the manipulation of curvature is not a difficult task. We expect to analyze this possibility in the near future.

Acknowledgments

This work was supported in part by DGAPA-UNAM, Grant no. IN106110. H. Quevedo would like to thank G. Camillis for interesting comments and suggestions.