Abstract

This paper is concerned with a kind of nonzero sum differential game of mean-field backward stochastic differential equations with jump (MF-BSDEJ), in which the coefficient contains not only the state process but also its marginal distribution. Moreover, the cost functional is also of mean-field type. It is required that the control is adapted to a subfiltration of the filtration generated by the underlying Brownian motion and Poisson random measure. We establish a necessary condition in the form of maximum principle with Pontryagin’s type for open-loop Nash equilibrium point of this type of partial information game and then give a verification theorem which is a sufficient condition for Nash equilibrium point. The theoretical results are applied to study a partial information linear-quadratic (LQ) game.

1. Introduction

Game theory had been an active area of research and a useful tool in many applications, particularly in biology and economics. The study of differential games was originally stated by Isaacs [1] and then summed up and developed by Basar and Olsder [2], Yeung and Petrosyan [3], and so forth. Berkovitz [4], Fleming [5], Elliott and Kalton [6], and Friedman [7] established the foundations for zero sum differential games and Varaiya [8] and Elliott and Davis [9] for stochastic differential games. Next, the advances in stochastic differential games continue to appear over a large number of fields. Please refer to Hamadène [10], Hamadène et al. [11], Altman [12], Wu and Yu [13], Yu and Ji [14], and Wang and Yu [15] for more information.

For the partial information two-person zero sum (or nonzero sum) stochastic differential games, the objective is to find a saddle point (or equilibrium point) for which the controller has less information than the complete information filtration . Recently, An and Øksendal [16, 17] and An et al. [18] established a maximum principle for partial information differential games of stochastic differential equations with jump (SDEJ). Wang and Yu [19] developed some results for optimal control of BSDEs and established a maximum principle for partial information differential games of backward stochastic differential equations (BSDEs). They established a necessary condition in the form of maximum principle with Pontryagin’s type for open-loop Nash equilibrium point of this type of partial information game and gave a verification theorem which is a sufficient condition for Nash equilibrium point. Meng and Tang [20] and Hui and Xiao [21] established a maximum principle for differential games of forward-backward SDE under partial information. Øksendal and Sulem [22] established a general maximum principle for forward-backward stochastic differential games for Itô-Lévy processes with partial information and applied the theory to optimal portfolio and consumption problems under model uncertainty, in markets modeled by Itô-Lévy processes.

To the best of our knowledge, there are few results about the partial information differential games of the discontinuous mean-field backward stochastic system. In the present paper we will research this topic. This paper is concerned with a new kind of nonzero sum differential game of mean-field backward stochastic differential equations with jump (MF-BSDEJ) under partial information. It is required that the control is adapted to a subfiltration of the filtration generated by the underlying Brownian motion and Poisson random measure. We establish a necessary condition in the form of maximum principle with Pontryagin’s type for open-loop Nash equilibrium point of this type of partial information game and then give a verification theorem which is a sufficient condition for Nash equilibrium point. We note that the state system and the cost function in [22] are not mean-field, and the game systems in [15, 19] are BSDEs. The theoretical results are applied to study a partial information linear-quadratic (LQ) game.

The rest of this paper is organized as follows. In Section 2, we state our partial information differential game of MF-BSDEJ and the main assumptions. Section 3 is devoted to the necessary optimality conditions. In Section 4, we obtain the sufficient maximum principle of differential game of MF-BSDEJ under partial information. In Section 5, we give a partial information linear-quadratic (LQ) game as example to show the applications of our theoretical results.

2. Statement of the Problems

Let be a completed probability space. We suppose that the filtration is generated by the following two mutually independent processes: a -dimensional standard Brownian motion and a Poisson random measure on , where is a nonempty open set equipped with its Borel field , with compensator , such that is a martingale for satisfying . is assumed to be a -finite measure on and called the characteristic measure. Let denote the class of -null elements of . For each , we define , where for any process , .

Let be the completion of the product probability space of the above with itself, where we define with and being the completion of . It is worthy of noting that any random variable defined on can be extended naturally to as with . For and so on, let be the set of random variable which is -measurable such that . For any , we denote Particularly, for example, if , then

We introduce the following notations: We use the usual inner product and Euclidean norm in , , and . The notation “ ” appearing in the superscripts denotes the transpose of a matrix. All the equalities and inequalities mentioned in this paper are in the sense of almost surely on .

This work is interested in a class of partial information nonzero sum differential games of MF-BSDEJ, which is inspirited by some interesting financial phenomena. For simplicity, we only consider the case of two players, which is similar for players. Let us now give a detailed formulation of the problem. Consider the following MF-BSDEJ: where , , and are the control processes of Player 1 and Player 2, and . We always use the subscript 1 (resp., the subscript 2) to characterize the variables corresponding to Player 1 (resp., Player 2). The mean-field backward game system (4) has the meaning that the two players work together to achieve a goal at the terminal time .

To study our problem, we give some assumptions on , , and . Let be a nonempty convex subset of and a given subfiltration which represents the information available to Player at time , respectively. Now we introduce the admissible control set Each element of is called an open-loop admissible control for Player . And is called the set of open-loop admissible controls for the players.

We assume that(H1) is continuously differentiable with respect to . Moreover, the norm of , , , , , , , is bounded by .

Now, if both and are admissible controls and assumption (H1) holds, then MF-BSDEJ (4) admits a unique solution (see Shen and Siu [23]). Ensuring to achieve the goal , the players have their own benefits, which are described by the following cost functionals: where ,   : ,     , satisfying the condition We also assume that(H2) is continuously differentiable in and its partial derivatives are continuous in and bounded by . Moreover, is continuously differentiable and is bounded by .

Suppose each player hopes to minimize her/his cost functional by selecting an appropriate admissible control . Then the problem is to find a pair of admissible controls such that We call the problem above a backward nonzero sum stochastic differential game, where the word backward means that the game system is described by a MF-BSDEJ. For simplicity, we denote it by Problem BNZ. If we can find an admissible control satisfying (8), then we call it an equilibrium point of Problem BNZ and denote the corresponding state trajectory by .

3. A Partial Information Necessary Maximum Principle

For the convex admissible control set, the classical way to derive necessary optimality conditions is to use the convex perturbation method. Let be an equilibrium point of Problem BNZ and let be the corresponding optimal trajectory. Let be such that . Since and are convex, for any , is also in . As illustrated before, we denote by and the corresponding state trajectories of game system (4) along with the controls and .

For convenience, we introduce the notations where denotes one of and .

We introduce the variational equations as follows: By (H1), it is easy to know that (10) admits unique adapted solution , .

For , , we set We have the following.

Lemma 1. Let assumptions (H1) and (H2) hold. Then, for ,

Proof. For , we have or where we denote Applying Itô’s formula to on , by virtue of (H1), we get By Gronwall’s inequality, we easily obtain the desired result. Similarly, we can show that the conclusion holds for .

Since is an equilibrium point of Problem BNZ, then

From this and Lemma 1, we have the following variational inequality.

Lemma 2. Let assumption (H1) hold. Then,

Proof. For , from (12), we derive Similarly, we have Let in (18); then, it follows that, for , (20) holds. Similarly, we can show that the conclusion holds for .

We define the Hamiltonian function , , as follows: Let

We introduce the following adjoint equation:

Starting from the variational inequality (20), we can now state necessary optimality conditions.

Theorem 3 (partial information necessary maximum principle). Suppose (H1) and (H2) hold. Suppose is an equilibrium point of Problem BNZ and is the corresponding state trajectory. Then one has that hold for any ., where is the solution of the adjoint equation (25).

Proof. For , applying Itô’s formula to , we obtain From Lemma 2, it follows that we have Because satisfies , we have This implies that Now, let be a deterministic element and let be an arbitrary element of the -algebra . And set It is obvious that is an admissible control.
Applying the above inequality with , we get which implies that Proceeding in the same way as the above proof, we can show that the other inequality holds for any . Then the proof is completed.

4. A Partial Information Sufficient Maximum Principle

In this section, we investigate a sufficient maximum principle for Problem BNZ. Let be a quintuple satisfying (4) and suppose that there exists a solution of the corresponding adjoint forward SDE (25). We assume that(H3)for , for all , is convex in , and is convex in .Let where denotes one of and .

Theorem 4 (partial information sufficient maximum principle). Assume that (H1)–(H3) are satisfied. Moreover, the following partial information maximum conditions hold: Then is an equilibrium point of Problem BNZ.

Proof. For any , we consider where Now applying Itô’s formula to on , we get Moreover, by virtue of (39) and convexity of , it instantly follows that where Noting the definition of and , we have where Using convexity of with respect to , we obtain Since , is minimal for and and are -measurable, we get Hence combining (43), (44), and (45), we obtain Therefore, it follows from (35), (40), and (46) that Then it implies that
In the same way Hence, we draw the desired conclusion. The proof is completed.

5. Application in a Partial Information LQ Case

In this section we work out an example of partial information linear-quadratic differential games of MF-BSDEJ to illustrate the application of the theoretical results. For notational simplification, we assume , , and .

Consider the following: The cost functional is where constants , . Functions , , , , , , , are bounded and deterministic; , , , are nonnegative, bounded, and deterministic; , , are positive, bounded, and deterministic; , , are also bounded. Our task is to find such that

Theorem 5. The mapping is one Nash equilibrium point for the above game problem, where is the solution of the following mean-field forward-backward stochastic differential equations with jumps (MF-FBSDEJ):

Proof. We first prove the existence of the solution of (54). We set Similar to Lemma 5.4 of [24], the optimal filter of  ,  satisfies Due to the above analysis, the candidate equilibrium point can be rewritten as where admits MF-FBSDEJ (56). We introduce a new MF-FBSDEJ: Based on the analysis above, we can say the existence and uniqueness of MF-FBSDEJ (56) are equivalent to those of MF-FBSDEJ (58). It is easy to check that MF-FBSDEJ (58) satisfies assumptions (A3)–(A5) with ,  , and . According to Theorem 7 in Appendix, there exists a unique solution  ,  of (58); here, Then there exists a unique solution of MF-FBSDEJ (56). Furthermore, there exists at most one equilibrium point for the underlying game.
Now we try to prove that is a Nash equilibrium point for our backward LQ game problem. We only prove It is similar to getting another inequality of (52). denotes the solution of the system Then Applying Itô’s formula to , we have As , , , noting that , we have So is a Nash equilibrium point for our backward LQ nonzero sum differential game problem.

6. Appendix

For the sake of convenience and completeness, we cite the existence and uniqueness theorem of MF-BSDEJ obtained by Shen and Siu [23]. They studied the following MF-BSDEJ: where , , is a random variable, and ;

They assumed that(A1)for each , , is an -measurable process defined on with ;(A2) satisfies Lipschitz condition: there exists a constant , such that Based on the fixed-point theorem, Shen and Siu [23] obtained the following existence and uniqueness result.

Proposition 6. One assumes that (A1) and (A2) hold. Then MF-BSDEJ (65) has a unique solution .

In the present paper we research the game problem of a MF-BSDEJ, so the game system and the adjoint equation constitute exactly a kind of initial coupled MF-FBSDEJ. Due to this, we give an existence and uniqueness theorem of MF-FBSDEJ. Consider the following MF-FBSDEJ: where , , is a random variable, and ; Given an full-rank matrix , let us introduce some notations where . Assume that(A3)for each , , is an -measurable process defined on with ;(A4) and satisfy Lipschitz conditions: there exists a constant , such that (A5) and satisfy monotonic conditions: where , , and are given nonnegative constants with . Moreover we have (resp., , ) when (resp., ).

By similar arguments of Yu and Ji [14], Wang and Yu [19], and Min et al. [25], we have the following existence and uniqueness theorem.

Theorem 7. One assumes that (A3), (A4), and (A5) hold. Then MF-FBSDEJ (68) has a unique solution .

7. Conclusion

In this paper, we investigate a new differential game problem of mean-field BSDE with jump (MF-BSDEJ). Compared with the previous literature, our game systems are mean-field BSDE with jump and are under the framework of partial information. We established a maximum principle and a verification theorem for an equilibrium point of nonzero sum differential games. We also give a partial information linear-quadratic (LQ) game as example to show the applications of our theoretical results.

The subject issue studied in this paper possesses fine generality. Firstly, the mean-field BSDEJ game system covers many systems as its particular case. For example, if we drop the terms on jump or mean-field or both of them, then the MF-BSDEJ can be reduced to MF-BSDE or BSDEJ or BSDE. Secondly, if we suppose that , for all , all the results are reduced to the case of full information. Thirdly, if the present nonzero sum stochastic differential game has only one player, the game problem is reduced to some related optimal control. Particularly, our results are a partial extension to differential games of full information BSDEs [15] and partial information BSDEs [19]. Finally, since many optimization and game problems in finance and economics can be associated with mean-field BSDE with jump, the outcomes of this paper can be widely applied in these areas.

Conflict of Interests

The authors declare that there is no conflict of interests regarding the publication of this paper.

Acknowledgments

The authors would like to thank the editors and the reviewers for their constructive comments and suggestions which helped them to improve this paper. This work was supported by the National Natural Science Foundation of China (Grant nos. 11371226, 11071145, 11301298, and 11231005), the Foundation for Innovative Research Groups of National Natural Science Foundation of China (Grant no. 11221061), the 111 Project (Grant no. B12023), and the Development Project of Shandong Province Science and Technology (Grant no. 2012GGB01241).