Abstract

This paper investigates the impact of the retailer’s overconfident behavior on supply chain performance. We start with a basic model on the rational newsvendor model and investigate the retailer’s optimal ordering decision and expected profit. Next, we extend the basic model and introduce an overconfident retailer. We find that the retailer’s overconfident behavior does not necessarily damage the supply chain compared with the basic model when the overconfident level does not exceed a threshold. We also design the cooperation and buyback mechanism and conduct numerical analysis to compare the manufacturer’s and retailer’s expected profits and real profits with those in the basic newsvendor model. It can achieve Pareto improvement in the supply chain when the overconfident level is low. When the retailer’s overconfident level exceeds a threshold, the retailer’s ordering decision cannot make the whole supply chain sustainable development.

1. Introduction

As a classical model in MS/OM, the newsvendor problem has been deeply explored; however, in reality the actual ordering of the newsvendor always deviates from the theoretically optimal result, and the actual ordering fluctuates around the theoretically optimal ordering quantity. Most scholars use the classical economic assumption that the decision-maker is a rational man, while he/she often has different decision-making behavior, and it is also illustrated in psychology that people cannot be entirely rational and often make irrational decisions [1, 2].

In recent years, decision-making has been becoming a hot issue along with the fact that consumer behavior was introduced into operational management. Scholars have proved the bias between cognitive reflection and decision-making by experiment and the decision-makers are prone to risk preferences, fairness preferences, eye tracking social preferences, overconfidence, and other preferences (see [37]). Among them, overconfident behavior becomes one of the hot spots and affects the operation management of the enterprise seriously. For instance, the high volume-trading problem [8], the bankruptcy because of the crazy mergers made by CEO [9], and the presence of oil or gas predicted by young geologist too confidently led to loss of millions of dollars [10]. Overconfidence has been explored deeply in the field of behavioral psychology, behavioral finance, and behavioral management but rarely in the field of management science and operations management. Croson et al. [11] first introduce overconfident behavior in supply chain management.

Based on the classical newsvendor model, we focus on the order variance when the decision-makers are overconfident and rational, respectively. Considering the cooperation and buyback mode, this paper illustrates how the retailer’s overconfident behavior affects her ordering decision and the profit of each member in the whole supply chain and how the manufacturer responds to encourage the overconfident retailer to decide the systematic optimal ordering quantity. The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. Section 2 reviews the relevant literature, and Section 3 describes the basic problem. Sections 4 and 5 discuss the basic model and overconfident retailer model, respectively. Section 6 discusses two kinds of decision-making mechanisms, the cooperation mode and buyback mode, and reports the results of an extensive numerical study, and Section 7 concludes this paper with a discussion of the results.

2. Literature Review

There are two primary streams of research that relate to our analysis: the literature on newsvendor problem and overconfident behavior. The newsvendor problem is a classic supply chain management issue which has been proposed in the fifties of the last century and has received wide attention in academia. Arrow et al. [12] analyzed the famous critical fractile solution for the newsvendor problem; after that, many scholars regard maximizing the expected profit as a decision objective and use the expected utility theory and mathematical model to explore the newsvendor problem. For example, Whitin [13] develops the newsvendor model where the demand is price dependent and follows a uniform distribution; moreover, he finds the optimal order which depends on the price variance under the objective of maximizing the expected profit. Thakkar et al. [14] investigated the optimal ordering quantity under the objective of maximizing the expected investment return and found wider application compared with the expected maximum. Khouja [15] classified the newsvendor problem into 11 categories, made a literature review on the predecessors’ research, and provided recommendations for future research. For recent reviews on the newsvendor model, refer to Petruzzi and Dada [16] and Qin et al. [17]. None of these papers consider the decision-makers’ decision behavior.

More recently, a stream of research has emerged that explored decision-makers’ behavior. For example, Eeckhoudt et al. [18] studied the risk-aversion behavioral decision-makers and found that decision-makers’ ordering quantity is always lower than the optimal ordering quantity. Many scholars have used experimental evidence to verify the existence of decision deviation. Schweitzer and Cachon [4] explain why retailers’ order differs from the expected profit-maximizing quantity and define the high (low) profit environment and find that decision-makers’ ordering quantity is less than (greater than) the optimal ordering quantity under the high (low) profit environment by experiments. Benzion et al. [19] test participants’ ordering decisions and show that the decision-makers have behavior preferences. In these behavioral preferences, the overconfident behavior is particularly prevalent and potentially harmful behavior [20]. Although many of these papers consider behavior preferences, few papers address the overconfident behavior in supply chain management.

Overconfident behavior is quite mature in psychology and has progress in the field of behavioral finance and behavioral management [21, 22]. But in the field of supply chain inventory management, the research on overconfidence is rare. Moore and Healy [23] define three types of overconfidence: overestimation, overplacement, and overprecision. People overestimate their actual capabilities, overplace their position among their colleagues or peers, and believe they are better than others. They believe that their predictions are more accurate than they actually are. This paper is also based on the third definition. Croson et al. [11] summarize the previous experimental study on human behavior, citing the third definition [23] overprecision, and use salvage costs and price adjustments to revise the overconfident retailer’s order decisions. Ren and Croson [24] and Proeger and Meub [25] provide experiment evidence for overconfidence as social bias. Unlike the present analysis, these papers do not analyze that the retailer’s and manufacturer’s profits can or cannot increase jointly after the implementation of the contract.

In this paper, we analyze the overconfident behavior in the traditional supply chain. In this setting, we consider a two-echelon supply chain that consists of one single manufacturer and one single retailer who is overconfident on the market demand. We discuss a basic model and then introduce an overconfident retailer. In addition, we also design the cooperation and buyback mechanisms and conduct a numerical analysis to compare the manufacturer’s and retailer’s expected profits and real profits with those in the basic newsvendor model.

3. Problem Descriptions

Consider a two-echelon supply chain, which is composed of one single manufacturer and one single retailer who has overconfident behavior on the market demand, and the manufacturer is the leader and the retailer is the follower in the supply chain. To be specific, the manufacturer is a risk-neutral decision-maker and does not have overconfident behavior, and the retailer is also a risk-neutral decision-maker and has overconfident behavior. The chronology of the event is that the manufacturer produces products and sells them to the retailer in wholesale price , and the retailer sells these products to the market in selling price . The manufacturer can predict the market demand accurately, and the demand follows a distribution with mean and variance   [11]. The market demand can be expressed as , where is a random variable, whose mean is 0 and variance is 1, and denote the CDF and PDF by and.

For the overconfident retailer, there is a deviation between the forecast demand and the actual demand. Thus, the cumulative distribution function is and the probability density function is . Refer to the definition of overconfidence defined by Moore and Healy [23], the forecast demand mean is not equal to the actual demand mean for the retailer overestimates the market environment and her ability. On the other hand, the overconfident retailer’s demand variance is less than or equal to the actual demand variance . Without loss of generality, the overconfident retailer’s forecast demand can be expressed as where indicates the retailer’s overconfident level, and . When , the retailer has no overconfident behavior; when , we have and the retailer behaves in an extremely overconfident manner and believes that the demand is constant. The closer is to 1, the more intense overconfidence the retailer behaves.

In the following discussion, let represent unit production cost. For unsold products, and represent unit salvage value that is disposed of by the retailer and manufacturer, respectively.

It is assumed that the above distribution functions are first-order differentiable and have strict monotone inverse function; these parameters satisfy the following relationship: where the first constraint is to ensure the wholesale price is higher than the manufacturer’s production cost and the retail price is higher than the wholesale price, in order to guarantee the retailer’s and manufacturer’s profits. The second constraint indicates that the residual value of the product is lower than the manufacturer’s production cost, and the residual value of the product in the retailer is less than that in the manufacturer, which illustrates that the manufacturer has the advantage in disposing the unsold products.

4. Basic Model

In this section, we first discuss a basic model where the manufacturer and the retailer are risk-neutral and rational. We assume the market demand of the product is , the demand distribution function is continuous and differentiable and is strictly increasing, the average demand is , and the variance is . The retailer’s ordering quantity is . When the market demand satisfies , the sale quantity is ; otherwise, the sale quantity is . Thus, the expected sale quantity is , and the expected unsold quantity is .

The retailer’s and the manufacturer’s profits are given by

The profit of the supply chain is given by

The objective of the retailer is to choose to maximize her profit. Besides, the expected profit function has a maximum because the second-order condition . Solving the first-order derivative of (3) with respect to , we can obtain

Thus, . is the retailer’s optimal ordering quantity in the newsvendor model, which is consistent with the results of Pasternack [26].

5. Overconfident Retailer Model

In this section, we consider an overconfident retailer who has an overconfident behavior on the market demand. In this case, the retailer’s ordering quantity is . When the market demand satisfies , the sale quantity is ; otherwise, . Therefore, . It can be rewritten as

The expected unsold quantity is .

In order to facilitate comparison with the expected profit under the basic model, we examine the relationship on the optimal ordering quantity between the rational retailer and the overconfident retailer in Theorem 1.

Theorem 1. The overconfident retailer’s optimal ordering quantity is

Proof. As discussed above, the rational retailer’s optimal ordering quantity is , and we define ; that is, .
Note that because , , and and follow the relationship that , we have .
As a result, the overconfident retailer’s optimal ordering quantity is .
And it can be rewritten as .
Finally, we have ; that is, .

Theorem 1 presents the overconfident retailer’s optimal ordering policy, and based on this result, we can derive some properties of the optimal ordering policy as follows.

Corollary 2. When , ; otherwise, .

Proof. According to the result of Theorem 1 that , we can obtain , so it is easy to obtain the conclusion of Corollary 2.

Subsequently, we consider the manufacturer’s and retailer’s expected profits separately. When the overconfident level is , the retailer’s expected profit can be expressed as where .

Making variable substitution to (9) according to (8), it is easy to see

Bringing (8) and (10) into (9), we can get

In the same logic, the manufacturer’s expected profit is

Under the conditions where the retailer disposes of the unsold products, the total profit of the supply chain is .

After simplifying, we can easily obtain .

Based on the optimal profits of the rational and overconfident retailers, we can derive the following results.

Corollary 3. When , the expected profit of the whole supply chain in the overconfident newsvendor model is less than that in the basic newsvendor model, and the expected profit of the whole supply chain decreases with . When , with increasing, the expected profit of the whole supply chain in the overconfident newsvendor model has two cases: it is either higher or higher first and then lower than that in the basic newsvendor model.

Proof. Compared with the basic newsvendor model, the real profit difference is
Therefore, solving the first-order derivative of with respect to , we can obtain
It is clear that and . When , we have . Since is an increasing function, this implies that is absolutely bigger than 0; that is, is increasing in . In particular, when , we have . Therefore, the profit difference is increasing in .
When , we have and and when is low, there is which made the equation set-up and satisfied ; that is, is always less than zero; when , , and if , is less than zero, and the profit difference decreases with ; if , is first less and then greater than zero and the profit difference is first decreasing and then is increasing in .

From Theorem 1 and Corollaries 2 and 3, we find that if , then ; thus, we have and , whereas if , ; thus, , . In other words, the bigger is, the bigger the ordering quantity deviates from the optimal one and results in lower profit.

Just as analyzed in Section 2, Gervais et al. [22], Glaser and Weber [8], and Malmendier and Tate [9] have provided enough evidences in financial field. We find that the overconfident behavior does not necessarily damage the supply chain, if the manufacturer can take advantage of the retailer’s overconfident behavior properly, such as subsidy or profit sharing mechanism which can improve the supply chain performance effectively. However, in the decentralized decision, both the retailer and the manufacturer maximize their own profits, and their decisions cause a double marginalization effect. What is worse, the overconfident behavior inevitably makes the retailer’s profit losses.

We know that when ; besides, the bigger is, the bigger deviates from and the lower the retailer’s profit is; when , then , and increasing leads to . Therefore, the manufacturer should sell products to the retailer with low wholesale price, which could reduce the retailer’s cost and then promote the retailer’s ordering quantity and profit.

6. Disposing Mechanism on Salvage Products

Based on the analysis of the impact of the retailer’s overconfident behavior on the supply chain, as a leader in the supply chain, the manufacturer should take effective measures to promote the retailer’s ordering decisions. Herz et al. [27], Choi et al. [28], and Govindan et al. [29] have done relevant research on supply chain coordination. Xu et al. [30] and Huang et al. [31] also analyzed such practical problems. In this section, we try to design and analyze two coordination mechanisms: cooperation mode and buyback mode.

6.1. Cooperation Mode

In this mode, we consider the manufacturer and retailer cooperate to dispose of the unsold products to realize a “win-win” situation. It is assumed that , which means that the manufacturer has the advantage in the disposing of the unsold products; therefore, the manufacturer disposes of the unsold products at the end of selling season. We also assume that the allocation rate of the residual value is . For unsold product, the manufacturer’s benefit is and the retailer’s benefit is .

We assume that the manufacturer knows the retailer’s overconfident level, and to manufacturer, the cost of the disposing of the unsold products is zero. Similar to the basic newsvendor model, in the corporation mode, the retailer believes her expected profit is

Solving the first-order derivative of (15) with respect to , we can derive the optimal ordering quantity as follows

From (16), the ordering quantity is increasing in . Therefore, a proper incentive can instruct the retailer to choose a proper ordering quantity.

The retailer believes that her profit is maximal when the optimal ordering quantity is (16). However, it is up to the actual market demand. Therefore, her real expected profit is

By the same logic, the manufacturer’s real expected profit is

And the real expected profit of the whole supply chain is

Since , we can obtain that , which is not necessarily equal to (16). Here we mark that . When the retailer chooses , the profit of the whole supply chain is maximized. Furthermore, from (19), the bigger the ordering quantity deviates from , the bigger the profit deviates from the maximum profit.

Compared with the basic newsvendor model, the profit difference is

Corollary 4. When , then and ; when , then and .

Proof. For any , we have and . When , we can obtain from Corollary 2 and then obtain .
Here we mark that ; then, . It is easy to see that which is similar to the proof of Theorem 1. When , we have and , and then . When , we obtain from Corollary 2; therefore, .

Corollary 5. When , then , and the bigger is, the bigger the expected profit of the whole supply chain deviates from the maximum profit.

Proof. In the case of , when the retailer chooses , the manufacturer can coordinate supply chain to maximize his profit; therefore, we have . Here we mark that the rational optimal ordering quantity is and the profit is ; thus, . According to the proof of Corollary 3, we concluded that the profit of the whole supply chain decreases with . Since and are fixed, we draw the conclusion that the bigger is, the bigger the expected profit of the whole supply chain deviates from the maximum profit.

Compared with the basic newsvendor model, the residual value of the unit product in the manufacturer is more than that in the retailer in the cooperation mode. Moreover, in the specific market environment, the manufacturer can make closer to through adjusting the size of .

Apparently, the retailer’s ordering quantity is affected mainly by the retailer’s overconfident level , demand mean , and the variance . In this section, we provide a numerical study to examine the impacts of the retailer’s overconfident behavior on the optimal ordering quantity and profits. We assume that the market demand follows a normal distribution , , , , , and , and we calculate that the retailer’s optimal ordering quantity is 161.1735, the retailer’s profit is 637.9868, the manufacturer’s profit is 483.5204, and the profit of the supply chain is 1121.5072 under the basic newsvendor model. We first analyze the circumstance of , and then let , and the specific dates are listed in Table 1.

From Table 1, the result that and decrease with may be different from our expectations. Many psychologists and scholars give explanations, such as Schweitzer and Cachon [4] who found that when the market is in a high-profit environment, decision-makers tend to order less and when the market is in a low-profit environment, decision-makers tend to order more. In addition, deviates from , which also examines the validity of Corollary 3. For a fixed , if decreases, then the retailer increases her ordering quantity, making the profit of the whole supply chain increase. Therefore, increasing the incentive properly can improve the performance of the supply chain, but it does not ensure that profits of the retailer and the manufacturer increase jointly.

Figure 1 shows an illustration of how , , and vary with and . In cooperation mode, when the retailer’s overconfident level is low, we have . This can be explained as follows. The main reason is that the manufacturer has the advantage in disposing of the unsold products compared with the retailer, which made the increased profit through cooperation larger than the loss caused by the ordering quantity deviation, and the retailer increases her ordering quantity when motivated by the manufacturer which made the total profit increase.

The results of Figures 2 and 3 indicate the impact of the overconfident level on expected profits of the retailer and manufacturer under different allocation rate . To be specific, when the overconfident level is low, for example, when , the expected profits of the retailer and manufacturer increase, which achieves the Pareto improvement, compared with the basic newsvendor model. For a fixed , and increase with the allocation rate , while decreases with it. Besides, when exceeds a threshold, the expected profits of the retailer and the manufacturer become smaller; thus, the supply chain profit is less than that in the basic newsvendor model. Therefore, from the manufacturer’s perspective, when is low, he can offer incentives to the retailer. However, when increases, he should reduce the allocation proportion to the retailer to ensure that their expected profit is no less than .

Next, we use another example to illustrate the impact of the overconfident behavior on the supply chain. We discuss the scenario of . In this example, the market demand follows the normal distribution and the values of other variables remain unchanged. The retailer’s optimal quantity is 73.4898 and profit is 773.0422 and the manufacturer’s profit is 220.4694 and the profit of the supply chain is 993.5116 under the basic newsvendor model. Let and specific data values are listed in Table 2.

From Table 2, the equation implied that the manufacturer can obtain more profits when the retailer is overconfident. Besides, increases and increases first and then decreases with . These results mean that the retailer’s overconfident behavior does not necessarily damage the supply chain. Meanwhile, if the manufacturer offers proper incentive to the retailer, the whole supply chain can achieve Pareto improvement. For example, when and is in a reasonable range, and hold. However, when exceeds a threshold, the manufacturer’s incentive has little impact on the retailer’s ordering decision and the retailer’s overconfident behavior brings more losses to the supply chain. In particular, when , the manufacturer’s incentive cannot impact the retailer’s ordering decision.

In order to illustrate the profit variance, we take different as presented in Figures 46.

We can see from Figure 4 that when , the manufacturer does not provide any incentives, and with the increase of , the profit of the whole supply chain is higher first and then lower than that in the basic newsvendor model, which examines the validity of Corollary 3. When the overconfident level is in a reasonable range, the profit of the whole supply chain increases with the allocation rate ; when exceeds a threshold, the profit of the whole supply chain has a downward trend, and the change of has little impact on the profit. From Figures 5 and 6, we have , regardless of the change of ; that is, the manufacturer can achieve Pareto improvement. We observe that a lower allocation rate allows a higher overconfident level . When is low, the incentive can make up for the losses caused by more orders, so ; when is high, the retailer’s order deviates from the optimal order.

It is worth pointing that the demand variance has a tremendous impact. For example, when the demand distribution follows and the other variables remain unchanged, whatever is, the manufacturer’s profit is higher than that in the basic newsvendor model, so when the manufacturer transfers all the residual value to the retailer, that is, , we have calculated that the manufacturer’s and retailer’s profit increase whatever is compared with basic newsboy model, which can achieve the Pareto improvement and examines the validity of Corollary 3.

6.2. Buyback Mode

In this mode, the manufacturer designs a buyback contract to encourage the retailer to order more products, the manufacturer buys back the unsold products and the buyback price is , and , which is to ensure that the buyback price is higher than the value of the retailer’s disposals. It is easy to see that, compared with the basic newsvendor model, the retailer can get more profits when the ordering quantity is the same.

When , the manufacturer does not take back unsold products; when , the retailer’s expected profit is the same no matter who deals with unsold products; when , the manufacturer transfers all the benefit from the unsold products to the retailer; when , the retailer has no ordering risk.

In the Stackelberg game, the manufacturer is the leader and the retailer is the follower. The chronology of the game event is given as follows. Firstly, before the selling season, the manufacturer informs the retailer about the wholesale price and the buyback price. Secondly, the retailer determines her ordering quantity based on this information. At the end of the selling season, the manufacturer pays for the unsold products to the retailer.

Similar to the basic model, the retailer’s real expected profit is .

It can be simplified as .

From the above equation, the optimal ordering quantity is . is decreasing in and increasing in . That is, the retailer hopes for a lower wholesale price and a higher buyback price.

In the buyback mode, the manufacturer’s real expected profit is and the real expected profit of whole supply chain is .

Compared with the basic newsvendor model, the profit difference is

Therefore, the manufacturer can adjust the wholesale price and the buyback price to make the retailer’s ordering decision closer to the optimal ordering quantity and then make the whole supply chain more efficient. If , the retailer does not sell unsold products to the manufacturer, so the manufacturer must keep .

First, we discuss the scenario that . The demand follows the normal distribution , and the values of other variables remain the same except and . Furthermore, the profits of the whole supply chain, the retailer, and the manufacturer are shown in Figures 79, respectively.

From Figure 7, the lower the wholesale price is and the higher the buyback price is, the greater the total profit is. This is because of the fact that a lower can encourage the retailer to increase her ordering quantity. We find it difficult to make the ordering quantity equal to . Therefore, in order to increase the profit of the whole supply chain, the manufacturer should offer incentives (such as improving the buyback price and reducing the wholesale price) on the premise that his profit is higher than that in the basic model.

From Figures 8 and 9, when the incentives are larger, that is, when is smaller and is bigger, apparently, the retailer’s profit increases. As is shown in Figure 8, when and , the retailer’s profit and the profit of the whole supply chain are significantly higher than other cases, but the manufacturer’s profit is lower than other cases.

Note that as long as is in a reasonable range, the supply chain can be coordinated. However, when exceeds a threshold, the whole supply chain cannot realize the Pareto improvement, and the reason is that since the manufacturer’s improvement measures have weaker impact on the retailer, he considers his own profit and does not offer the retailer any incentive for avoiding or reducing the loss.

Next, we discuss the scenario of . The demand follows the normal distribution , and the values of other variables remain the same except and . The profits of the whole supply chain, the retailer, and the manufacturer are shown in Figures 1012, respectively.

Figure 10 illustrates when is low, increasing the incentive can increase the profit of the whole supply chain, and when is high, the incentive measure has little effect. Therefore, the manufacturer does not need to take more measures to support the retailer when is high.

The results of Figures 11 and 12 indicate the impact of the overconfident level on expected profits of the retailer and the manufacturer under different . First of all, the manufacturer’s profit increases with , and this is because the retailer’s ordering quantity increases with . To achieve Pareto improvement, when is low, the manufacturer does not need to offer too many incentives; when is not very high, the manufacturer should offer more incentives to ensure that the retailer’s profit is higher than that in the basic model. When exceeds a threshold, if the manufacturer sets to a very high value, then the manufacturer’s profit is less than that in the basic model; on the other hand, if the manufacturer sets to a low value, the retailer’s profit is less than that in the basic model.

We address the differences between this paper and Croson et al. [11]. First, different from the buyback contract and the wholesale price contract in Croson et al. [11], we analyze the cooperation mode and buyback mode. In this paper, the buyback price is larger than 0, and strictly speaking, is larger than the salvage value . However, in their paper, the buyback price can be lower than 0. If it is negative, the retailer does not sell unsold products to the manufacturer. Secondly, in our paper, the manufacturer can make the retailer and the manufacturer achieve Pareto improvement by adjusting and . They do not consider the change of the retailer’s and manufacturer’s profit after the implementation of the contract.

6.3. Results Analysis

The comparison of the two modes: in the cooperation mode, the manufacturer and retailer can better exchange information and views; meanwhile, it enables the retailer to listen to the manufacturer’s recommendations, which is useful for reaching the Pareto improvement by reallocating the residual value of the unsold products; while in the buyback mode, the manufacturer can adjust the wholesale price and the buyback price, and the range of is larger than . In the buyback mode, in the scenario of , when is high, the manufacturer can reduce the wholesale price . In the scenario of , when is high, the manufacturer can increase the wholesale price . In the cooperation mode, the manufacturer can do little when is high.

In the wholesale price contract, only can be changed, while in the buyback contract, not only but also can be changed. In the wholesale price contract, the manufacturer may realize Pareto improvement by reducing when is low. In the buyback mode, can be increased or reduced, and the supply chain can realize the Pareto improvement when is low, and the manufacturer can also gain more profits by changing , and it is difficult in the wholesale price contract. As the retailer’s overconfident behavior may cause more ordering, the retailer must dispose of them by herself in the wholesale price contract; thus, we take the buyback contract to share the supply chain risk. In short, compared with the wholesale price contract and the cooperation mode, the buyback mode is the optimal choice for the manufacturer.

7. Conclusions

Overconfident behavior has largely been overlooked in the supply chain management literature. This paper attempts to fill the gap. Our premise is that the retailer has overconfident behavior on the market demand. In this setting, we start with a basic model and analyze the retailer’s optimal ordering decision. In the model of overconfident newsvendor, we analyze the overconfident retailer’s optimal ordering decision and compare the optimal ordering decisions in the traditional and overconfident newsvendor models. We find that when , the expected profit of the whole supply chain in the overconfident newsvendor model is less than that in the basic newsvendor model, and with the retailer’s overconfidence level increasing, the expected profit of the whole supply chain decreases. When , with the retailer’s overconfidence level increasing, the expected profit of the whole supply chain in the overconfident newsvendor model has two cases: it is either higher or higher first and then lower than that in the basic newsvendor model. In other words, overconfident behavior does not necessarily damage the supply chain.

In terms of ordering deviation and profit losses caused by the retailer’s overconfident behavior, we discuss two mechanisms: the cooperation mode and the buyback mode. Besides, we reallocate the residual value of the unsold products in them creatively in the cooperation mode and analyze the ordering decision by the Stackelberg game in the two modes. Moreover, we document the results of a numerical study to further illustrate the effects of the overconfident level on the ordering quantity and profits. We find that when is low, the supply chain can achieve Pareto improvement by reasonable incentive. When exceeds a threshold, the whole supply chain cannot realize the Pareto improvement, and at this time since the manufacturer’s improvement measures have weaker impact on the retailer, the retailer’s ordering decision cannot make the whole supply chain sustainable development. Therefore, it is harmful for the supply chain when the overconfident level is high.

There are several directions for future research. First, the manufacturer needs to design contracts to manage the retailer’s overconfident behavior and coordinate supply chain and it would be an important topic in the future. Besides, in practice, the manufacturer generally franchises more than one retailer to sell their products; thus, considering two or more retailers to compete in selling could present interesting opportunities for future research.

Conflict of Interests

The authors declare that there is no conflict of interests regarding the publication of this paper.

Acknowledgments

The authors sincerely thank the editor and the anonymous reviewers for their constructive and important comments on the paper. Lei Xu’s research is partially supported by the National Natural Science Foundation of China, Grant no. 71302005; Humanities and Social Sciences Foundation of Ministry of Education in China, Grant no. 14YJC630049; and the Scientific Development Strategy Project of Tianjin, Grant no. 13ZLZLZF03500.