Complexity

Complexity / 2020 / Article

Research Article | Open Access

Volume 2020 |Article ID 5282035 | 11 pages | https://doi.org/10.1155/2020/5282035

An Agent-Based Model of Opinion Polarization Driven by Emotions

Academic Editor: Giulio Cimini
Received30 Aug 2019
Revised28 Jan 2020
Accepted18 Mar 2020
Published10 Apr 2020

Abstract

We provide an agent-based model to explain the emergence of collective opinions not based on feedback between different opinions, but based on emotional interactions between agents. The driving variable is the emotional state of agents, characterized by their valence, quantifying the emotion from unpleasant to pleasant, and their arousal, quantifying the degree of activity associated with the emotion. Both determine their emotional expression, from which collective emotional information is generated. This information feeds back on the dynamics of emotional states and individual opinions in a nonlinear manner. We derive the critical conditions for emotional interactions to obtain either consensus or polarization of opinions. Stochastic agent-based simulations and formal analyses of the model explain our results. Possible ways to validate the model are discussed.

1. Introduction

In the past decades, the significance of emotions in opinion formation and decision making has been recognized by the scientific community, and its study is mainly pioneered by the field of behavioral economics and empirical psychology. Experimental research on individual behavior shows that emotions fuel information sharing [1], that emotional arousal drives reactions to become more extreme [2], and that emotional states frame the way we process information [3]. Recent results on observational data analysis suggest that collective opinions and decisions, such as election outcomes or pricing dynamics, can be influenced by emotional states like collective mood. A notable example has been the analysis of mood in Twitter and the stock market [4, 5], which led to further studies of Twitter emotions in pricing of other assets like Bitcoin [6].

The modelling of emotions and opinions has mainly focused on their interaction at the individual level, modelling how affective and cognitive mechanisms influence each other [7]. This has left aside the modelling of the interplay between emotions and collective opinions, mainly due to the absence of data to test those models and the technical challenge to formulate and test hypotheses on them. Our aim in this article is to fill that gap, proposing a computational model of collective opinions and emotions. Such a model, when designed based on plausible and testable assumptions, can be used as a hypothesis generator to guide future empirical research [8].

We apply the principles of a modelling framework of collective emotions in which the collective state arises through interactions via a common information field and not through one-on-one interactions [9]. The individual dynamics of this model have been calibrated against results from self-reports [10] and empirical data on the dynamics of emotional interaction [11]. We model how the opinions of agents are influenced by a common information field accessible to all agents, capturing this way how opinions evolve as a function of shared emotions. We present analytical and numerical results on this model that constitute stylized facts that can be tested in future empirical studies.

2. Background

Emotions are psychological states of high relevance for the individual that imply cognitive and physiological effects. They are closely related to our behavior and how we interpret our own actions [12]. Current research in affective science conceives emotions through their measurable components or dimensions, proposing models to quantify and measure them. Among these models, the component process model of emotions [13] conceptualizes emotions as composed of sequential appraisal processes, such as evaluating if an event is positive or adverse, and parallel processes that include physiological dynamics, action tendencies, and subjective feelings.

In terms of measurement of emotions, the circumplex model of core affect [14] focuses on emotions on a short timescale in which they do not have a clear target. Emotions in the circumplex model consume energy in the organism and strongly affect cognition and action tendencies, like verbal expression. The circumplex model provides the quantitative basis for our approach: emotions are quantified by a dimension of valence (pleasure associated with the emotion) and of arousal (degree of activity induced by the emotion). These two dimensions allow the mapping of emotions in a circle that captures a large amount of the variance of emotional experience [15]. While further dimensions are informative of the experience of emotions, like potency and unpredictability [16], valence and arousal have prevailed as the two major factors to measure short-lived emotional states. Recent research has modelled emotions as dynamical systems. For example, Sander et al. [17] modelled emotional fight-or-flight reactions as cusp catastrophes, and empirical studies have calibrated the internal relaxation and variation dynamics of emotions against empirical data [10, 18, 19].

The emotions of humans do not exist in isolation and often collective emotional states are triggered or emerge in a crowd. Collective emotions are defined as emotional states shared by large amounts of people at the same time [20]. Research on collective emotions, while learning from established works from social psychology and sociology, is still a growing field [21, 22]. The hyperlens model of social regulation of emotion is an adaptation of previous models of social factors of emotions to capture collective aspects of emotional life [23]. This model calls research to “get out of the lab” and investigate collective emotions in the naturalistic scenarios where they appear. Studies on shared emotions in collective gatherings have shown the long-term effects of these collective emotions for the feelings of social cohesion and identity of those involved [24]. Similarly collective emotions and group-based emotions play key roles in intergroup conflicts [25].

The availability of data produced by the digital society motivated the study of collective emotions in online communities and social media. Collective emotions have been analyzed through sentiment analysis of real-time group chats [26], product reviews [27], and of forum discussions [28]. To understand their emergence and dynamics, the Cyberemotions modelling framework was designed to simulate collective emotions in a vast variety of online media [9]. The Cyberemotions framework was designed to be testable in both controlled experiments and observational analyses of digital traces, following a wider trend of calibrating agent-based models against large-scale datasets [29]. Models in the Cyberemotions framework have been used to explain polarization of emotions in product reviews [27], collective emotions in chatrooms [26, 30] and in blogs [31], and emotion spreading in the MySpace social network [32]. Further applications of this framework have focused on modelling how bots and dialog systems could drive collective mood in a discussion [3335] and to drive the emotion dynamics of 3D virtual humans in real-time interaction [36]. We follow the Cyberemotions framework in our model design to produce generalizable and testable formulations that can be put in reference to previous empirical and analytical results.

While such results from data-driven modelling of emotions were quite convincing, recent proposals to formally relate emotion dynamics to opinion dynamics have received much less evidence and support. Opinion dynamics itself is an established field of research and one of the areas, where methods from statistical physics have been successfully applied to model social phenomena [37, 38]. A highly relevant question tackles the emergence of consensus and polarization, motivating bounded confidence models [3941], information accumulation systems in modular networks [42], and studies of the role of biased assimilation and assortativity in the polarization of opinions [43, 44].

To link emotions and opinion polarization, recent computational models simply rephrased the dimension of valence as opinion, to then study cusp catastrophes of state changes depending on arousal [45, 46] and on tolerance parameters inherited from bounded confidence models [47]. To date, what is missing is a model that includes both the fast dynamics of emotional states and the slower dynamics of opinions in an integrated approach that can explain the role of emotions in opinion polarization. This needs to be done based on principles testable in psychological studies and observational analyses, rather than recasting previous models by simply replacing the terminology of opinions for the one of emotions. We aim to fill this gap by formulating such model and providing an analysis of its dynamics, opening new research questions for future empirical research.

3. Agent-Based Model

3.1. Modeling Emotional Dynamics

The main focus of our model is to explain the evolution of opinions based on emotions. Precisely, we do not assume that agents respond to the opinions of other agents, directly. Instead, we assume that the expression of opinions is tightly coupled to the expression of emotions, and these emotions in fact influence other agents. This allows us to build on our previously developed agent-based framework of emotional influence [9]. It has proven to describe collective emotional states in different social systems [26, 27, 31, 35].

3.1.1. Emotional Information

Here, we only recap the core dynamics of our agent-based framework of emotional influence, schematically shown in Figure 1. The horizontal layer represents the agent. Its emotion is characterized by the two dimensions valence and arousal . Both determine the content of the written expression , which contributes, e.g., to an online discussion, as follows:

Agent makes an individual contribution if its arousal exceeds a given individual threshold . is the Heaviside function: only if . The threshold is a random value selected uniformly from an interval . This assumption is aligned with previous models in this framework [9] and matches empirical results in which the probability to participate in empirical discussions grows steadily with arousal after a minimum value [11]. If an agent expresses itself, the emotional content of that contribution results from its valence at that time, precisely from the sign of its valence, i.e., positive or negative, but the amount of the contribution, , is a parameter equal for all agents.

The emotional information generated this way by all agents participating is contained in the information field . It consists of two components, and , which contain the emotional expressions with positive or negative valence, respectively. The dynamics for each component is given bywhere represents either or . It is increased by all agents, , that make a positive/negative contribution at time , but can also decay over time at a rate , which reflects the decay of attention for older information. For simplicity, we assume that is the same across agents, but future model can include heterogeneus impact following the patterns captured by Social Impact Theory [48, 49]. captures emotional information resulting from external influences, e.g., influences from the media, but is neglected in the following.

We further define

This way, the total information field accumulates the emotional expressions of all agents in a weighted manner, i.e., with some memory because of the exponential decay. can be seen as a measure of the activity of the agents, as it directly builds on their contributions. On the other hand, is a measure of the average emotional charge, i.e., the average valence of the information field.

Dynamics of valence and arousal: As indicated in Figure 1, the information field further influences the agent, affecting the individual valence and arousal. Hence, the vertical layer represents the indirect emotional communication between agents, i.e., their coupling by means of the emotional information field. This requires us to determine how the individual valence and arousal are affected by the emotional information . For the dynamics of both variables, we have proposed stochastic equations that follow the modelling framework of Brownian agents [50], i.e., we have a superposition of deterministic and stochastic influences:

Here, and denote the strength of the stochastic influences, whereas and are numbers randomly chosen from a standard normal distribution. The damping constants , ensure that in the absence of any influences, both valence and arousal of an agent relax in the course of time (silent mode). The terms and are nonlinear functions to capture the influence of valence and arousal, and the available emotional information as given in equation (3). To specify them, we use the general form of a power series:

This approach matches the observed dynamics in experiments of emotion interaction in online media [11]. Higher exponents in the above polynomials were not found to be informative in regression analysis of emotion changes during online interaction, and the value of parameters in the above equation can be chosen with respect to the observed empirical dynamics.

Regarding the sign and value of the coefficients , , we just summarize the detailed discussion in [9]. For the dynamics of valence, we have considered contributions up to 3rd order. If we want to ensure a “silent mode,” has to be chosen. Further, if we want to avoid a built-in preference for either positive or negative valence values. With this, we have for the dynamics of valence [9]

To prevent a valence explosion, in this dynamics , i.e., a saturation behavior for large valence values, has to be chosen. With this, we further see that nontrivial solutions can be only obtained if . Specifically, has to be reached. This condition is likely met for large values of the emotional information , i.e., already from this condition, we can expect a transition toward a strong emotional regime (characterized by large absolute values of valence) if the emotional information is sufficiently large.

For the dynamics of arousal, we have considered contributions up to 2nd order, i.e.,

Our model requires a small initial positive bias, , in order to start the communication process in the absence of previous interactions. To allow for solutions characterized by at least two different activity levels (low and high arousal), we further have to choose and . The expected collective dynamics then very much depends on the sign of . For , the arousal dynamics becomes saturated. If this saturation level is above the individual threshold , the agent will generate an emotional expression and is set back to zero afterwards. If, at that point, fluctuations push the agent’s arousal to negative values, it will not return to positive arousal again. Hence, we obtain a scenario where agents express their emotions most likely only once. This may lead to collective emotions, but not repeatedly.

For , however, we may obtain two different stationary solutions with negative arousal. At low levels of emotional information , e.g., after some silent periods, fluctuations are able to push the agent’s arousal to positive values, from where a new communication cycle starts. Hence, we obtain a scenario in which waves of collective emotions over time can be expected.

We note that in both cases, fluctuations play an important role in establishing an active regime. They first push agents to a positive arousal which is then amplified by the positive feedback, until it reaches the threshold. This then generates emotional expressions that establish a communication field which in turn feeds back on the agent’s valence and arousal. In our model, valence decides about the “content,” determining the sign of the emotional information generated. Arousal, on the other hand, decides about the activity pattern.

3.2. Modeling Opinion Dynamics

We now have to specify how the emotional interaction described above influences the dynamics of opinons. We will proceed in two steps: first we introduce the dynamics of opinions and subsequently the coupling between opinions and emotions.

Specifically, our model shall explain the polarization of opinions. In politics, such a polarized state can be illustrated by the opposition between democrats and republicans, which each represent particular opinions towards a given set of subjects. Obviously, in this context, the opinion of a particular agent at time cannot be represented as a binary variable, e.g., , as this would imply that a disagreement with automatically translates into an agreement with . Also, to extend the opinion space to include a neutral opinion, e.g., , does not really solves the problem, as it neglects the heterogeneity of agents with respect to their opinions. Therefore, a continuous variable would be the most appropriate approach.

Given that opinions are continuous variables, consensus has to be defined as a certain (narrow) range of opinions or, more precisely, as a certain distribution of opinions, , with a mean value and a (small) variance . Polarization, on the other hand, should be defined by a bimodal distribution of opinions , with a large variance . The two distant peaks represent the polarized opinions, while modest opinions in the middle range are less frequent.

To specify the dynamics of opinions, we start with the general ansatz of a power series already employed in equation (5).which postulates a nonlinear feedback of the current opinion of an agent on the change of this opinion. The power series accounts for the fact that we need additional assumptions that later can be encoded in the coefficients . is a stochastic term, to consider random influences on the opinion.

For our discussion, we will use terms up to 3rd order from the power series. Neglecting individual differences and stochastic influences for the moment, we can express the opinion dynamics as

To discuss the possible stationary solutions, of equation (9), for the moment we assume that and . Then, we find

I.e., to obtain nontrivial values for the opinion, and have to be of opposite sign. The two possible cases are illustrated in Figure 2, where is plotted against according to equation (9). We note that for , solutions with extreme opinions are always instable. In particular, there is a force toward the neutral opinion , i.e., it would be difficult to explain polarization of opinions based on such a parameter constellation.

For , , on the other hand, we find that there can be a stable coexistence of extreme opinions. Hence, in the following, we choose . This also accounts for a saturation dynamics in the case of extreme opinons. With that, it is obvious that we will have only one possible solution for the opinion, i.e., , if . However, if , we will find bimodality, i.e., always two opposing opinions, whereas the neutral opinion is instable. This is the case of polarization, we are interested in. The corresponding bifurcation diagram is shown in Figure 3(a), where we vary as the control parameter.

To understand the impact of on the opinion dynamics, let us now fix , i.e., we allow for polarized opinions in principle. For simplicity, we still neglect , but we will include a nonnegligible influence later in the discussion. The corresponding bifurcation diagram is shown in Figure 3(b), where we keep fixed, but vary as the second control parameter. If and is large, then we find only one stationary solution for opinion, which is negative, i.e., . If and is large, then we find only one stationary solution for opinion, which ispositive, i.e., .

For intermediate values of , we find a regime where there is bimodality of the opinions with different weights of the positive or negative solution and instable solutions to separate these. Hence, dependent on the concrete values of , we can expect regimes in which we find a coexistence of polarized opinions, but as well regimes where only one opinion emerges.

3.3. Nonlinear Coupling between Emotions and Opinions

In order to couple the opinion dynamics to the emotional interactions of the agents, we need to determine how the coefficients may depend on emotions. We set , i.e., make it proportional to the overall activity in emotional interactions, expressed by the value of the emotional field. This activity has to overcome some threshold value expressed by , in order to allow for a sufficient coupling. Considering a small baseline value , without activity, i.e., without emotional emotional information, is negative and there is only a neutral opinion, according to the above discussion. But high activity, i.e., large emotional information, will drive to positive values, to allow for bimodality.

In our model, and do not depend on the emotional dynamics. maybe close to zero. It can be positive or negative, this way generating a global bias toward left/right opinions. determines the saturation level of the opinions. In agreement with equation (10), the smaller , the larger the possible polarization of opinions.

The important parameter for the coupling between emotions and opinions is , for which we assume . If the emotional activity, expressed by is very high and the average emotion is either very negative or very positive, then there is likely only one opinion, which is also very likely very negative or very positive. Precisely, if and is high, then and is large and we find . If and is high, then and is large and we find . In accordance with Figure 3(b), for moderate values of and we can expext bimodality, i.e., a polarization of opinions.

In conclusion, the dynamics of the opinions read nowwhere , are some proportionality constants. They are chosen between 0 and 1 to mitigate the influence of the corresponding terms.

Relations to the bounded confidence model: To further understand this dynamics, let us neglect all small or higher-order terms and focus on the core dynamics, which reads for an individual agent :

For the mean opinion in the agent population, we find

This leads, in equilibrium, , to , and the opinion dynamics, equation (12), simplifies towhich is precisely the bounded confidence dynamics with . That means, the higher the activity as measured by , the faster the convergence toward the mean. A noticeable difference: in the bounded confidence model, agents only interact if . In our case, all agents interact through the communication field , more precisely via the mean valence . In the following, we make use of the fact that the average valence can be approximated by the difference in the two field components, , , equation (3) and choosewhich reduces the number of variables and parameters.

Very similar to the bounded confidence model, we should expect scenarios that can lead to consensus characterized by a unimodal opinion distribution. However, as we already know from the above discussion, the inclusion of the terms , neglected in this derivation may lead to other scenarios of coexistence characterized by a bimodal opinion distribution. Hence, while and are essential to couple the opinion dynamics to the emotion dynamics, and may decide about the level of polarization reached.

4. Results

4.1. Agent-Based Simulations

We first present the results of agent-based computer simulations, to verify that the model works as expected. The parameter values not explicitly mentioned in the following are chosen, in accordance with [11], as follows:

Figure 4 shows, in the left panel, the opinion trajectories of individual agents over time and, in the right panel, the distribution of opinions after a sufficiently long time. We note that, because the model is intrinsically stochastic, we do not reach a stationary distribution in the strict sense.

As the first observation, we find indeed the polarization of opinions that were initially close, i.e., drawn from a normal distribution . This was expected because the range of parameters was adjusted such that a polarization regime emerges. However, we emphasize that some of the , namely, and , are in fact not constants, but functions of the emotional field components , which in turn depend on the agents’ individual valence and arousal. Hence, these “parameters” were not chosen, but their value emerged from the emotional interactions between agents. Moreover, these values are not fixed but fluctuate over time according to the emotional dynamics. This leads to the nonstationary opinion dynamics observed.

As the second observation, we see that the number of agents with positive and negative opinions can differ significantly dependent on the parameter . Although it is small, it generates a global preference for either left or right opinions. Consequently, we find also the emergence of a minority/majority in the agent population. This is shown in different heights of the peaks of the bimodal distributions.

Eventually, we can also obtain scenarios in which consensus is reached, i.e., instead of a bimodal opinion distribution, we find a unimodal distribution. This is illustrated in Figure 5 for a consensus around the neutral opinion and a biased opinion.

4.2. Critical Transitions toward Polarized Opinions

To fully understand the role of the coefficients in equation (9), we now focus on the so-called phase portrait. Different from Figure 2, which plots against , the phase portrait investigates against . With equation (9), the two variables of the phase portrait follow the dynamics:

These two coupled equations can be solved numerically using a 4th order Runge–Kutta method. The results are shown in Figure 6. Stationary solutions of the opinions are given by . But, as the distribution of the colored squares along this horizontal line in Figure 6 verifies, the solutions concentrate on the left/right end of the horizontal line, indicating polarized opinions. The middle-ranged values of resulting from are in fact unstable stationary solutions.

The range of these unstable solutions can be obtained by setting in equation (17). As the result, we findwhere and follow from the above quadratic equation:

These values are clearly indicated in Figure 6 by the two (empty) vertical regions around in which the arrows of the vector field change their direction.

So where do agents end up with their opinions dependent on their initial conditions, if we only consider the deterministic dynamics? This is answered by the separatrix also depicted in Figure 6 as the thick-dashed line. Agents starting with initial conditions above the separatrix will tend to obtain a positive in the long run, while agents starting with initial conditions below the separatrix will reach a negative . The precise equation for the separatrix is given by

The only difference in the expression is in the values , , which, when taken at first order in , can be reduced to

It is important to notice that the dynamics captured by the phase portrait, shown in Figure 6, does not depend on . The coefficient merely selects a solution curve and can be seen as a vertical shift in the diagram.

5. Discussion

In this paper, we have provided a model to formally link the dynamics of emotions to the dynamics of opinions. We follow an agent-based approach, that is, we focus on the emotions and opinions of individual agents with heterogeneous properties. Our research interest is to explain the emergence of collective opinions based on the emotional interaction between agents. More specifically, we want to understand under which conditions we obtain consensus, i.e., the emergence of one common opinion (reflected in a narrow opinion distribution), or polarization, i.e., the emergence of two opposing common opinions (reflected in a bimodal opinion distribution). As the interaction mechanism, we do not assume a feedback between different opinions, which would be the most simple way to obtain the two distinct opinion distributions. Instead, our main assumption is that the dynamics of opinions is driven by the dynamics of emotions.

Following established measures from social psychology, the dynamics of emotions is characterized by two agent variables, valence, the pleasure associated with emotions and arousal, the activity associated with emotions. Both variables determine the emotional expression of agents, from which collective emotional information is generated. This is quantified by two aggregated and time-dependent variables, the emotional field and the average valence, . These two variables from the emotional interaction feedback on the individual opinion dynamics in a nonlinear manner. Our formal model makes transparent under which critical conditions for the emotional interaction, we can expect a polarization of opinions, without assuming a direct interaction on the level of opinions.

Our modelling approach fits a general framework to model active matter [38], a term to denote systems with the ability of self-organization, active motion, and structure formation, provided a critical supply of energy. In our case, the driving variables describe the emotional state, composed of valence and arousal, whereas the driven variable is the individual opinion, . Different from other approaches, our model respects the fact that emotions and opinions evolve on two different time scales. Emotions relax faster than opinions, i.e., they evolve on a shorter time scale, and the resulting values for the mean valence and the emotional field subsequently drive the evolution of opinions.

Validation scenario: Our investigations point to real-world mechanisms in the formation of opinions which, in addition to rational considerations, are very much dependent on sentiment. Because the measurement of emotions is simpler than a corresponding measurement of opinions (see Section 2), our model can be potentially validated against data. For instance, we are able to measure the emotional information from online communication in fora. From the user comments in fora, valence can be quantified by means of refined sentiment analysis tools, such as lexicon-based techniques. This would allow to estimate as a real value between and 1. To estimate the value of the emotional information , we can use the total amount, or even a time series, of comments. This would also allow to estimate values for the parameter for the relaxation dynamics.

In order to validate the link between emotion dynamics and opinion dynamics, we also need to estimate the polarization of opinions. Several previous works have analyzed polarization as manifested in social media and digital traces [41, 5154]. Here, we see three avenues on how polarization has been analyzed and how it can be used to validate our model:Polarization from the final amount of likes/dislikes: This dichotomoy constrains opinions as strictly positive or negative, not neutral. Data, e.g. from Reddit or Youtube [5557] allows us to calculate the ratio of agents with positive and negative opinions and to link this ratio to different collective emotion scenarios (expressed by and ).Polarization from the coexistence of positive and negative expressions of opinions: Using sentiment analysis methods, we can estimate the polarization of a discussion in terms of the simultaneous presence of positive and negative expressions [58]. For very big and longitudinal data, we can obtain the final distribution of opinions , to calculate the overall polarization. Changes in the distribution and the subsequent polarization measure could then be related to changes in the emotional information.Polarization from the existence of network components: The online communication between users can be represented as a social network, on which we can perform a community analysis, to detect communities with different opinions [6]. This method makes sense if links signal agreement or endorsement, like retweets or follower links.

Extension to multi-dimensional opinion space: Our model so far considers that opinion is a scalar, i.e. there is only one opinion per agent, which is with respect to one subject only. This one-dimensional description already grafts the dichotomy in favor/against into the opinion space. In most real situations, however, one could agree with individual on one particular subject and with on another one. Hence, more complex mixed opinions should be possible in an extension of our model. For this we could redefine the opinion of agent as a vector, where expresses the opinion of agent towards subject at time . It then depends on the context how emotions drive opinions in different dimensions.

We emphasize that a multi-dimensional opinion space exacerbates the problem of consensus, i.e. the convergence toward a common opinion. Convergence along one dimension does not necessarily implies agreement on other subjects. On the contrary, agents which agree on given subjects often choose to disagree on other subjects, to distinguish themselves from other agents. Hence, we expect that instead of consensus we frequently find coexistence of (mixed) opinions. In developed democracies such as Switzerland, this has lead to the emergence of a political space with many parties coexisting, which opens the possibility to form alliances regarding certain decisions [6].

It is an open question how to define a multidimensional polarization measure based on mixed opinions. This will be addressed in a subsequent publication. Another open question regards the link of such measures to available data. For this, we could consider a topic model to reduce the dimensionality of the opinion space. With a smaller number of opinion dimensions, we can then test correlations to identify additional polarization levels.

Data Availability

The manuscript does not have any data.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare that they have no conflicts of interest.

Acknowledgments

All authors acknowledge funding from the Swiss National Science Foundation (CR21I1_146499). D.G. acknowledges funding from the Vienna Science and Technology Fund through the Vienna Research Group Grant “Emotional Well-Being in the Digital Society” (VRG16-005).

References

  1. J. Berger, “Arousal increases social transmission of information,” Psychological Science, vol. 22, no. 7, pp. 891–893, 2011. View at: Publisher Site | Google Scholar
  2. R. Reisenzein, “The Schachter theory of emotion: two decades later,” Psychological Bulletin, vol. 94, no. 2, pp. 239–264, 1983. View at: Publisher Site | Google Scholar
  3. N. Schwarz, H. Bless, and G. Bohner, “Mood and persuasion: affective states influence the processing of persuasive communications,” Advances in Experimental Social Psychology, vol. 24, pp. 161–199, 1991. View at: Publisher Site | Google Scholar
  4. J. Bollen, H. Mao, and X. Zeng, “Twitter mood predicts the stock market,” Journal of Computational Science, vol. 2, no. 1, pp. 1–8, 2011. View at: Publisher Site | Google Scholar
  5. M. Lachanski and S. Pav, “Shy of the character limit: “twitter mood predicts the stock market” revisited,” Econ Journal Watch, vol. 14, no. 3, p. 302, 2017. View at: Google Scholar
  6. D. Garcia, A. Abisheva, S. Schweighofer, U. Serdült, and F. Schweitzer, “Ideological and temporal components of network polarization in online political participatory media,” Policy & Internet, vol. 7, no. 1, pp. 46–79, 2015. View at: Publisher Site | Google Scholar
  7. J. P. Forgas, “Affect and cognition,” Perspectives on Psychological Science, vol. 3, no. 2, pp. 94–101, 2008. View at: Publisher Site | Google Scholar
  8. E. R. Smith and F. R. Conrey, “Agent-based modeling: a new approach for theory building in social psychology,” Personality and Social Psychology Review, vol. 11, no. 1, pp. 87–104, 2007. View at: Publisher Site | Google Scholar
  9. F. Schweitzer and D. Garcia, “An agent-based model of collective emotions in online communities,” The European Physical Journal B, vol. 77, no. 4, pp. 533–545, 2010. View at: Publisher Site | Google Scholar
  10. P. Kuppens, Z. Oravecz, and F. Tuerlinckx, “Feelings change: accounting for individual differences in the temporal dynamics of affect,” Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, vol. 99, no. 6, pp. 1042–1060, 2010. View at: Publisher Site | Google Scholar
  11. D. Garcia, A. Kappas, D. Kuster, and F. Schweitzer, “The dynamics of emotions in online interaction,” Royal Society Open Science, vol. 3, no. 8, Article ID 160059, 2016. View at: Publisher Site | Google Scholar
  12. N. H. Frijda, “Emotion, cognitive structure, and action tendency,” Cognition & Emotion, vol. 1, no. 2, pp. 115–143, 1987. View at: Publisher Site | Google Scholar
  13. K. R. Scherer, “On the nature and function of emotion: a component process approach,” Approaches to Emotion, vol. 2293, p. 317, 1984. View at: Google Scholar
  14. J. A. Russell, “A circumplex model of affect,” Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, vol. 39, no. 6, pp. 1161–1178, 1980. View at: Publisher Site | Google Scholar
  15. K. R. Scherer, “What are emotions? And how can they be measured?” Social Science Information, vol. 44, no. 4, pp. 695–729, 2005. View at: Publisher Site | Google Scholar
  16. J. R. J. Fontaine, K. R. Scherer, E. B. Roesch, and P. C. Ellsworth, “The world of emotions is not two-dimensional,” Psychological Science, vol. 18, no. 12, pp. 1050–1057, 2007. View at: Publisher Site | Google Scholar
  17. D. Sander, D. Grandjean, and K. R. Scherer, “A systems approach to appraisal mechanisms in emotion,” Neural Networks, vol. 18, no. 4, pp. 317–352, 2005. View at: Publisher Site | Google Scholar
  18. T. Lodewyckx, F. Tuerlinckx, P. Kuppens, N. B. Allen, and L. Sheeber, “A hierarchical state space approach to affective dynamics,” Journal of Mathematical Psychology, vol. 55, no. 1, pp. 68–83, 2011. View at: Publisher Site | Google Scholar
  19. M. Pellert, S. Schweighofer, and D. Garcia, “The individual dynamics of affective expression on social media,” EPJ Data Science, vol. 9, no. 1, pp. 1–14, 2020. View at: Publisher Site | Google Scholar
  20. C. Von Scheve and S. Ismer, “Towards a theory of collective emotions,” Emotion Review, vol. 5, no. 4, pp. 406–413, 2013. View at: Publisher Site | Google Scholar
  21. A. Goldenberg, D. Garcia, E. Halperin, and J. J. Gross, “Collective emotions,” Current Directions in Psychological Science, vol. 19, no. 2, 2020. View at: Google Scholar
  22. C. von Scheve and M. Salmella, Collective Emotions, OUP, Oxford, UK, 2014.
  23. A. Kappas, “Social regulation of emotion: messy layers,” Frontiers in Psychology, vol. 4, p. 51, 2013. View at: Publisher Site | Google Scholar
  24. D. Páez, B. Rimé, N. Basabe, A. Wlodarczyk, and L. Zumeta, “Psychosocial effects of perceived emotional synchrony in collective gatherings,” Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, vol. 108, no. 5, pp. 711–729, 2015. View at: Publisher Site | Google Scholar
  25. A. Goldenberg, T. Saguy, and E. Halperin, “How group-based emotions are shaped by collective emotions: evidence for emotional transfer and emotional burden,” Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, vol. 107, no. 4, pp. 581–596, 2014. View at: Publisher Site | Google Scholar
  26. A. Garas, D. Garcia, M. Skowron, and F. Schweitzer, “Emotional persistence in online chatting communities,” Scientific Reports, vol. 2, no. 1, p. 402, 2012. View at: Publisher Site | Google Scholar
  27. D. Garcia and F. Schweitzer, “Emotions in product reviews–empirics and models,” in Proceedings of the 2011 IEEE Third Int’l Conference on Privacy, Security, Risk and Trust and 2011 IEEE Third Int’l Conference on Social Computing, pp. 483–488, Boston, MA, USA, October 2011. View at: Publisher Site | Google Scholar
  28. A. Chmiel, J. Sienkiewicz, M. Thelwall et al., “Collective emotions online and their influence on community life,” PLoS One, vol. 6, no. 7, Article ID e22207, 2011. View at: Publisher Site | Google Scholar
  29. S. Fortunato, M. Macy, and S. Redner, “Editorial,” Journal of Statistical Physics, vol. 151, no. 1-2, pp. 1–8, 2013. View at: Publisher Site | Google Scholar
  30. B. Tadić, V. Gligorijević, M. Mitrović, and M. Šuvakov, “Co-evolutionary mechanisms of emotional bursts in online social dynamics and networks,” Entropy, vol. 15, no. 12, pp. 5084–5120, 2013. View at: Google Scholar
  31. M. Mitrović and B. Tadić, “Dynamics of bloggers’ communities: bipartite networks from empirical data and agent-based modeling,” Physica A: Statistical Mechanics and Its Applications, vol. 391, no. 21, pp. 5264–5278, 2012. View at: Publisher Site | Google Scholar
  32. B. Tadić, M. Šuvakov, D. Garcia, and F. Schweitzer, “Agent-based simulations of emotional dialogs in the online social network myspace,” in Cyberemotions, pp. 207–229, Springer, Berlin, Germany, 2017. View at: Google Scholar
  33. S. Rank, M. Skowron, and D. Garcia, “Dyads to groups: modeling interactions with affective dialog systems,” International Journal of Computational Linguistics, vol. 4, no. 1, pp. 22–37, 2013. View at: Google Scholar
  34. M. Skowron, S. Rank, D. Garcia, and J. A. Hołyst, “Zooming in: studying collective emotions with interactive affective systems,” in Cyberemotions, pp. 279–304, Springer, Berlin, Germany, 2017. View at: Google Scholar
  35. B. Tadić and M. Šuvakov, “Can human-like bots control collective mood: agent-based simulations of online chats,” Journal of Statistical Mechanics: Theory and Experiment, vol. 2013, no. 10, Article ID P10014, 2013. View at: Publisher Site | Google Scholar
  36. J. Ahn, S. Gobron, D. Garcia, Q. Silvestre, D. Thalmann, and R. Boulic, “An NVC emotional model for conversational virtual humans in a 3D chatting environment,” in International Conference on Articulated Motion and Deformable Objects, pp. 47–57, Springer, Mallorca, Spain, July 2012. View at: Google Scholar
  37. C. Castellano, S. Fortunato, and V. Loreto, “Statistical physics of social dynamics,” Reviews of Modern Physics, vol. 81, no. 2, pp. 591–646, 2009. View at: Publisher Site | Google Scholar
  38. F. Schweitzer, “Sociophysics,” Physics Today, vol. 71, no. 2, pp. 40–46, 2018. View at: Publisher Site | Google Scholar
  39. M. Del Vicario, A. Scala, G. Caldarelli, H. E. Stanley, and W. Quattrociocchi, “Modeling confirmation bias and polarization,” Scientific Reports, vol. 7, no. 1, p. 40391, 2017. View at: Publisher Site | Google Scholar
  40. J. Lorenz, “Continuous opinion dynamics under bounded confidence: a survey,” International Journal of Modern Physics C, vol. 18, no. 12, pp. 1819–1838, 2007. View at: Publisher Site | Google Scholar
  41. A. L. Schmidt, F. Zollo, M. Del Vicario et al., “Anatomy of news consumption on facebook,” Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, vol. 114, no. 12, pp. 3035–3039, 2017. View at: Publisher Site | Google Scholar
  42. J. K. Shin and J. Lorenz, “Tipping diffusivity in information accumulation systems: more links, less consensus,” Journal of Statistical Mechanics: Theory and Experiment, vol. 2010, no. 06, p. P06005, 2010. View at: Publisher Site | Google Scholar
  43. P. Dandekar, A. Goel, and D. T. Lee, “Biased assimilation, homophily, and the dynamics of polarization,” Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, vol. 110, no. 15, pp. 5791–5796, 2013. View at: Publisher Site | Google Scholar
  44. M. Mäs and A. Flache, “Differentiation without distancing. Explaining Bi-polarization of opinions without negative influence,” PLoS One, vol. 8, no. 11, Article ID e74516, 2013. View at: Publisher Site | Google Scholar
  45. P. Sobkowicz, “Discrete model of opinion changes using knowledge and emotions as control variables,” PLoS One, vol. 7, no. 9, Article ID e44489, 2012. View at: Publisher Site | Google Scholar
  46. P. Sobkowicz, “Quantitative agent based model of user behavior in an internet discussion forum,” PLoS ONE, vol. 8, no. 12, Article ID e80524, 2013. View at: Publisher Site | Google Scholar
  47. P. Sobkowicz, “Extremism without extremists: deffuant model with emotions,” Frontiers in Physics, vol. 3, no. 17, 2015. View at: Publisher Site | Google Scholar
  48. B. Latan, “The psychology of social impact,” American Psychologist, vol. 36, no. 4, pp. 343–356, 1981. View at: Publisher Site | Google Scholar
  49. A. Nowak, J. Szamrej, and B. Latané, “From private attitude to public opinion: a dynamic theory of social impact,” Psychological Review, vol. 97, no. 3, pp. 362–376, 1990. View at: Publisher Site | Google Scholar
  50. F. Schweitzer, Brownian Agents and Active Particles: Collective Dynamics in the Natural and Social Sciences, Springer, Berlin, Germany, 2003.
  51. M. Del Vicario, A. Bessi, F. Zollo et al., “The spreading of misinformation online,” Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, vol. 113, no. 3, pp. 554–559, 2016. View at: Publisher Site | Google Scholar
  52. A. Matakos, E. Terzi, and P. Tsaparas, “Measuring and moderating opinion polarization in social networks,” Data Mining and Knowledge Discovery, vol. 31, no. 5, pp. 1480–1505, 2017. View at: Publisher Site | Google Scholar
  53. S. Yardi and D. Boyd, “Dynamic debates: an analysis of group polarization over time on twitter,” Bulletin of Science, Technology & Society, vol. 30, no. 5, pp. 316–327, 2010. View at: Publisher Site | Google Scholar
  54. F. Zollo, A. Bessi, M. Del Vicario et al., “Debunking in a world of tribes,” PLoS One, vol. 12, no. 7, 2017. View at: Publisher Site | Google Scholar
  55. A. Abisheva, D. Garcia, and F. Schweitzer, “When the filter bubble bursts: collective evaluation dynamics in online communities,” in Proceedings of the 8th ACM Conference on Web Science, pp. 307-308, Hannover, Germany, May 2016. View at: Google Scholar
  56. A. Abisheva, V. R. K. Garimella, D. Garcia, and I. Weber, “Who watches (and shares) what on youtube? and when? using twitter to understand youtube viewership,” in Proceedings of the 7th ACM International Conference on Web Search and Data Mining, pp. 593–602, New York, NY, USA, February 2014. View at: Google Scholar
  57. D. Garcia, A. Abisheva, and F. Schweitzer, “Evaluative patterns and incentives in youtube,” in Proceedings of the International Conference on Social Informatics, pp. 301–315, Springer, Oxford, UK, September 2017. View at: Google Scholar
  58. D. Garcia and F. Schweitzer, “Social signals and algorithmic trading of bitcoin,” Royal Society Open Science, vol. 2, no. 9, p. 150288, 2015. View at: Publisher Site | Google Scholar

Copyright © 2020 Frank Schweitzer et al. This is an open access article distributed under the Creative Commons Attribution License, which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited.


More related articles

395 Views | 241 Downloads | 0 Citations
 PDF  Download Citation  Citation
 Download other formatsMore
 Order printed copiesOrder

Related articles

We are committed to sharing findings related to COVID-19 as quickly and safely as possible. Any author submitting a COVID-19 paper should notify us at help@hindawi.com to ensure their research is fast-tracked and made available on a preprint server as soon as possible. We will be providing unlimited waivers of publication charges for accepted articles related to COVID-19. Sign up here as a reviewer to help fast-track new submissions.