Abstract

We examine the effects of policy lags on local economic stability using a Kaldorian model. This study analyzes two cases: the case of a monetary policy with a time lag and the case of a policy with both fiscal and monetary lags. Similar to the case of fiscal policy lags examined in a previous study, monetary policy lags have destabilizing effects on economic stability. However, in the case of the existence of both fiscal and monetary policy lags, there is a possibility that a monetary policy lag can stabilize an economy.

1. Introduction

In this study, we investigate the effects of policy lags (i.e., fiscal and monetary policy lags) on the stability of an economy. As the analytical framework, we employ a traditional Keynesian macrodynamic model. In general, two types of time lags have been studied: distributed and fixed lags. The present study focuses on the fixed lag (the time-to-build model developed by Kalecki [1] is the origin of economic models that consider a fixed lag; Szydłowski [2, 3] develops Kalecki’s [1] model to incorporate the factors of economic growth; economic models that introduce a distributed lag include Fanti and Manfredi’s [4] dynamic IS-LM model and Yoshida and Asada’s [5] Keynes-Goodwin model; Yoshida and Asada also examine the case of a fixed policy lag).

One of the representative traditional Keynesian macrodynamic models is the dynamic IS-LM model developed by Schinasi [6] and Sasakura [7]. In a previous study, De Cesare and Sportelli [8] develop a dynamic IS-LM model with a tax collection lag. Furthermore, Matsumoto and Szidarovszky [9] use the dynamic IS-LM model to compare the case of a fixed lag with that of a distributed lag in tax collections and demonstrate that a larger stable region can be established in the case of a fixed lag compared with a distributed lag. Both of these studies evidently show that a policy lag restricts the ability of traditional fiscal policies to stabilize an economy.

The Kaldorian model originated in the studies of Kaldor [10] and Chang and Smyth [11] is another representative model of the traditional Keynesian macrodynamic model. Asada and Yoshida [12] introduce a fiscal policy lag into this model and demonstrate that an increase in the responsiveness of a fiscal policy can lead to local instability, as is the case with the dynamic IS-LM model.

Recently, economic models that consider two time lags have been developed. For example, Zhou and Li [13] propose a dynamic IS-LM model with two capital accumulation lags (Zhou and Li’s [13] model can be considered as an extension of Cai’s [14] model, which is a dynamic IS-LM model with only one capital accumulation lag). Sportelli et al. [15] present a similar model with two time lags in the public sector: government expenditure and tax collection lags. Moreover, Matsumoto and Szidarovszky [16] propose a nonlinear multiplier-accelerator model with investment and consumption lags. These studies demonstrate that the steady state fluctuates between stability and instability with an increase in a certain policy lag; that is, multiple stability switches can occur.

In the present study, we first propose a Kaldorian model that only introduces the monetary policy lag, which can be considered as the monetary policy lag version of Asada and Yoshida’s [12] model, and perform a local stability analysis. Furthermore, we propose a model that considers the existence of both fiscal and monetary policy lags. For the analysis of this model, we employ the mathematical method developed by Gu et al. [17]. Their method enables us to represent a stability crossing curve (a curve that separates stable and unstable regions on a lag parameter plane) as a perfectly parameterized form. Before the advent of Gu et al.’s [17] method, one could only represent one lag as a function of another lag. Using their method, we can present a more exact figure of a stability crossing curve. Few studies have employed this method for economic analysis.

This study proceeds as follows. Section 2 presents a dynamic system that represents a model economy, while Section 3 examines the local stability in the case of a monetary policy with a lag. Subsequently, Section 4 examines the case wherein both fiscal and monetary policy lags exist. Finally, Section 5 presents our conclusion.

2. The Model

2.1. Basic Equations

The model economy comprises the following equations:where = real national income; = real private consumption; = real private investment; = real government expenditure; = real income tax; = real capital stock; = nominal interest rate; = nominal money supply; = adjustment speed of the goods market; = marginal propensity to consume; = base consumption; = marginal tax rate; = real subsidy; = activeness level of fiscal policy; = target level of real national income; = target level of real government expenditure; = price level; = activeness level of monetary policy; = target level of nominal money supply; = time; = fiscal policy lag; and = monetary policy lag.

Equations (1), (2), (3), and (4) represent a disequilibrium adjustment function of the goods market, a consumption function, a tax collection function, and an investment function, respectively. Equation (5) represents a fiscal policy reaction function with a government expenditure lag, while (6) signifies a capital accumulation function. For simplicity, we assume that capital does not depreciate. Equation (7) represents the monetary market equilibrium condition, where the left-hand side denotes real money balance and the right-hand side indicates real money demand (in this study, we assume that the price level is constant; by assuming (where ), we can allow for variations in the price level; however, this change does not affect the nature of our argument). Here, we ensure that the adjustment of the monetary market is rapid, and therefore the balance of demand and supply of this market is always maintained. Finally, (8) represents a monetary policy reaction function with a money supply lag.

If real money balance is constant (i.e., ), then the system compounded from (1)–(8) essentially becomes similar to that of Asada and Yoshida [12]. However, the assumptions of and significantly complicate the dynamic property of the system, thereby resulting in a major change in the economic implication of time lags.

2.2. Summarization

We summarize (1)–(8) in a two-dimensional dynamic system. First, by substituting (8) into (7) and solving for , we obtainwhere and .

Furthermore, by substituting (3) into (2) and substituting (9) into (4), we obtain

Finally, by substituting (5), (10), and (11) into (1) and substituting (11) into (6), we obtain the following system of differential equations with two time delays:

2.3. Linearization

We assume that steady-state solutions and that satisfy exist and these solutions are continuous with respect to all parameters. In order to analyze the local stability around the steady-state point , we linearize the system and obtainwhere , , , and .

Assuming the exponential functions and , where and are arbitrary constants and denotes the eigenvalue, as the solutions of system (13) and substituting these into the system, we obtain

For nontrivial solutions to exist, the determinant of the left-hand side matrix, denoted by , must be equal to zero; that is,whereEquation (15) is a characteristic equation of system (13). The significant feature of this equation is found in the existence of the exponential terms and .

First, we examine the case of no policy lags. By substituting into (15), we obtainwhich is an ordinary quadratic equation of .

Thus, if (i.e., the coefficient of from (17) is positive), the real parts of the roots of (17) are negative (see Chapter 18 in Gandolfo [18] for details regarding the relation between the roots and the coefficients of a quadric equation). In contrast, if , the real parts of the roots are positive. Thus, if , then the steady state is locally stable, and if , then it is unstable.

The larger the values of and are, the more likely the stability condition holds (note that ). Therefore, if policy lags do not exist, then traditional fiscal and monetary policies could function effectively for stabilization.

In the following discussion, we assume that if both fiscal and monetary policy lags do not exist, then an economy is stable; that is, we have the following.

Assumption 1. We have

Under this assumption, we analyze the effects of the policy lags on stability.

Incidentally, if , then both roots of (17) are conjugate complex. Furthermore, by defining , the conditions for Hopf bifurcation are satisfied at ; that is, (i) (17) includes a pair of pure imaginary roots and (ii) . Therefore, a cycle exists for a certain range of in the neighborhood . We can develop a similar argument using the monetary policy parameter .

3. Case of Monetary Policy with a Lag

Asada and Yoshida [12] examine the situation where a time lag exists in fiscal policy responses, which is equivalent to the case wherein and in system (12). In this section, we analyze the situation where a time lag exists in monetary policy responses by assuming that and in system (12).

In this case, the characteristic equation in (15) can be rewritten as follows:

The following analysis is based on the study of Matsumoto and Szidarovszky [19] (Bellman and Cooke [20] provide a helpful introductory textbook of delay differential equations). The procedures of the analysis are given as follows:(1)We characterize the points (if any) at which the dynamics around the steady state can change, that is, the points at which a zero real root or pure imaginary roots appear. These points are referred to as “crossing points.”(2)We reveal the directions of the changes in the signs of the real parts that occur when crosses the crossing points.

3.1. Crossing Points

First, we examine whether the points at which a zero real root appears can exist. By substituting into (19), we obtain . However, since and , this equality cannot hold. Accordingly, cannot be a root.

Next, we examine whether the points at which the pure imaginary roots appear can exist. By substituting , where = imaginary part (pure imaginary roots are always conjugated; therefore, we can assume without loss of generality) and , into (19), we obtain Application of Euler’s formula () to this equation yields This equality holds only when both real and imaginary parts of the left-hand side equal zero; that is,Or, equivalently,For values of that satisfy these equations, (19) includes pure imaginary roots, where , .

Furthermore, the sum of the squares of (22) yields the following: Solving for , we obtainwhere .

We denote real and positive values of by . By substituting into (23) and solving for , we obtainThus, there exists an infinite number of values of (i.e., ) that generate pure imaginary roots (i.e., crossing points).

Finally, if a real and positive value of does not exist, then changes in the signs of the real parts of the roots do not occur. Therefore, in this case, a policy lag does not affect stability.

Direction of Crossing. Here, we reveal how the signs of the complex roots change when crosses . This is determined by the sign of . If , then the signs of the real parts of the roots change from negative to positive with an increase in (which indicates destabilization). In contrast, if , then the signs of the real parts of the roots change from positive to negative with an increase in (which indicates stabilization). For convenience of calculation, we will observe the sign of instead of that of .

Using (19), we can demonstrate that holds for any value of (see the appendix). Thus, with any crossing, the signs of the real parts of the roots change from negative to positive.

If a policy lag does not present (), then roots with positive real parts do not exist under Assumption 1. With increases in , the number of roots with positive real parts increases by two. Accordingly, we can state that roots with positive real parts exist in the region of (where ). Therefore, we can offer the following proposition.

Proposition 2. For , the steady state is stable, and, for , it is unstable.

This proposition suggests that even if a monetary policy is sufficiently active enough to satisfy Assumption 1, an economy can become unstable due to the existence of a policy lag. A similar result has already been shown by Asada and Yoshida [12] concerning fiscal policies.

3.2. Numerical Simulations

Let us consider a numerical example. Following the study of Asada and Yoshida [12], we set baseline parameters, as shown in Table 1.

Furthermore, Asada and Yoshida [12] employ the investment function that is highly nonlinear with respect to , which is formulated as follows (in their model, ):Based on these assumptions, the steady-state values are provided by .

We also set the baseline values of and as and , respectively (generally, it seems that the responsiveness of monetary policies to economic fluctuations is often larger than that of fiscal policies; therefore, we assume ). When is fixed at the baseline value, exists only for . Outside this range, a policy lag does not affect stability. In addition, Assumption 1 is satisfied for . Accordingly, irrespective of the value of a monetary policy lag, the steady state is unstable for , and it is stable for .

Likewise, when is fixed at the baseline value, exists for . In addition, Assumption 1 is satisfied for . Hence, the steady state is stable for , irrespective of the value of a lag.

Figure 1 describes () that corresponds to as a function of and . These curves are referred to as “crossing curves.” Here, the stability condition is expressed as . Therefore, we can state that an increase in has a stabilizing effect, whereas that in has a destabilizing effect.

Thus, an increase in the activeness level of a monetary policy may cause instability due to the existence of a monetary policy lag. A similar result concerning a fiscal policy has already been shown by Asada and Yoshida [12].

Incidentally, conditions for Hopf bifurcation are satisfied at ; that is, (i) (19) includes a pair of pure imaginary roots and (ii) . Therefore, when crosses , a cycle emerges. A similar argument can be developed using and . We now suppose that . In this case, a bifurcation diagram can be described for , as shown in Figure 2 (the vertical axis represents the maximal and minimal values of ). This figure shows that not only one period but also multiple period cycles can emerge. The emergence of multiple period cycles is attributed to the strong nonlinearity of the investment function with respect to . When we use the investment function that has relatively simpler form with respect to as below (we set the coefficient of as so that the value of equals that of (28)), the bifurcation diagram becomes as shown in Figure 3. In this case, only one period cycle exists. Hence,

Although Asada and Yoshida [12] do not clearly specify the time dimension, similar models that include a disequilibrium adjustment function of the goods market ( is set around unity) specify the measure of as a year (refer to, e.g., Yoshida and Asada [5]). Therefore, we will consider the time dimension as a year. For example, when , the steady state is unstable for years.

4. Case of Policies with Fiscal and Monetary Policy Lags

In this section, we investigate the case wherein both fiscal and monetary policy lags exist (i.e., and ). In order to examine the signs of the roots of (15), we use a mathematical method developed by Gu et al. [17].

4.1. Preconditions

First, to apply the technique of Gu et al. [17], some preconditions should be examined. According to their study, (15) should satisfy the following conditions:(I).(II).(III)A solution common to all three polynomials , , and does not exist.(IV).

Condition (I) is satisfied by , while Condition (II) is also satisfied by . Condition (III) is obviously satisfied. Finally, Condition (IV) is satisfied by .

Now, we examine the effects of lags on the stability of the steady state. The analysis proceeds as follows:(1)We characterize the sets (i.e., crossing sets) at which the pure imaginary roots appear (it is ensured from precondition (II) that zero cannot be a root).(2)We depict the crossing sets on the plane (which we refer to as the crossing curves) via numerical simulation.(3)We reveal the directions of changes in the signs of the real parts that occur when lags cross the crossing curves.

4.2. Crossing Sets

Dividing (15) by , we obtainwhere

Denoting a pure imaginary root by , the values of that satisfy (30) can be characterized by the following lemma.

Lemma 3 (see [17, Proposition ]). For each satisfying , is a solution of for some if and only if

We denote the set of that satisfy conditions (32) as , which is termed the “crossing frequency.” For all , the sets satisfying (30) (i.e., crossing sets) should satisfy the following conditions (Figure 4):where .

Incidentally, on the complex plane, multiplication of amplitudes becomes a sum of the parts; therefore, we obtain

In addition, Figure 4 demonstrates that the following relations hold:

Moreover, after some manipulation, (31) derive the following expressions:

Thus, using (34) to (36), (33) can be rewritten as follows:where the interior angles of the triangle denoted by and are given by the cosine theorem as follows:

Equations (37) characterize the crossing sets . Depending on the signs of and , we can define two types of crossing sets, denoted by and , as follows:

As in the previous section, we set parameter values and the functional form of the investment function, as shown in Table 1, (28) or (29), and . In this case, crossing frequency is provided by (Figure 5) (according to Gu et al.’s [17] classification, Figure 5 exhibits Type 13). For , describing the crossing sets and on the - plane, we obtain Figure 6, where and . The dotted curves represent , and the solid curves represent . The points marked by a dot indicate the starting points of both curves, that is, the points corresponding to .

We establish how the real parts of the roots change when lags cross the crossing curves with an increase in . For , if , then the real parts of the roots change from negative to positive; this indicates destabilization. In contrast, if , then the real parts of the roots change from positive to negative; this indicates stabilization.

Differentiating (30) with respect to , we obtain or, equivalently,where

Describing the real parts of (40) as a function of , we obtain Figure 7, where the dotted curves are the functions evaluated on curve and the solid curves are the functions evaluated on curve . As for curve , stabilization only occurs on the intermediate region of the segments ; destabilization occurs on the other segments of . As for curve , destabilization occurs on all segments. Here, we define a curve formed by connecting curves (where and ) as (Figure 8). We also define a curve formed by connecting the points on curve that minimize the value of for a given as curve . Then, we can express the stability condition as follows: set exists in the left-hand side region of curve .

On curve , conditions for Hopf bifurcation are satisfied, and therefore a cycle emerges. In addition, as is obvious from Figure 6, an increase in the fiscal policy lag necessarily destabilizes the steady state. However, an increase in the monetary policy lag has the potential to stabilize the steady state, which depends on the value of . When , we can see that the steady state fluctuates between stability and instability with an increase in . Such a phenomenon cannot be observed in models with only one time lag. Moreover, Figure 9 presents a bifurcation diagram wherein and (28) is used as the investment function. This figure evidently indicates that alternations of stability and instability emerge with an increase in .

In particular, when , stability can be established by setting , , or ; that is, for equilibrium stability, monetary policy lag should be less than one year, between 3 and 4.5 years, or between 6.8 and 7.5 years when a fiscal policy lag is approximately three months.

Next, we examine how and affect the stability condition. Both and affect and through . It is difficult to analytically show how and change. Hence, we numerically examine how curve (which comprises and ) shifts when and increase from each baseline value ( and ).

Figures 10 and 11 describe curve in cases with and , respectively. We can observe that an increase in shifts curve to left. Accordingly, the stability region reduces. Likewise, Figures 12 and 13 describe curve in cases with and , respectively. The stability region is also reduced by an increase in . These results suggest that increases in the activeness levels of fiscal and monetary policies increase economic instability, as is the case with only one policy lag.

4.3. Investment and Stability

In general, the formulation of the investment function has great significance to stability in macrodynamic models; that is, the larger the marginal propensity to investment is, the more likely it becomes unstable. In this subsection, we examine the effects of changes in the partial derivatives of the investment function, and , on stability. We compare three cases: the case of no policy lags, the case of the existence of only monetary policy lag, and the case of the existence of both fiscal and monetary policy lags.

In the case with no policy lags, and affect the stability condition given by Assumption 1 through . The smaller the values of and are (the larger the absolute value of is), the more likely the stability condition is satisfied. These are fairly typical results.

In the case of a monetary policy with a lag, and affect the value of through ( also directly affects ). Accordingly, the value of (27) changes. In this case, it is difficult to analytically show the quality and quantity of these effects. Hence, we resort to a numerical method. Based on the parameter values proposed in Section 3.2, crossing curves can be described within each range of and that ensure the existence of , as shown in Figure 14. The region located below these curves indicates the stability regions. Similar to the case with no policy lags, an increase in causes destabilization. However, due to the concavity of the crossing curve, there is a possibility that a decrease in causes destabilization. Thus, the existence of a lag complicates the effects of investment on stability.

Finally, we investigate the case wherein both fiscal and monetary policy lags exist. In this case, and affect the stability condition (i.e., location of curve ) through , , and . According to numerical simulations, increases in the absolute values of and generally shift the curve toward the left. Therefore, these changes decrease the stability region. However, if completely shifts even to the negative region of , then the curve that specifies the stability region is no longer but is . For example, when , the stability region is defined as the left-hand side region of the curve in Figure 15. However, when , the stability region is defined as the left-hand side region of the curve in Figure 16. Thus, an increase in may increase the stability region.

5. Conclusion

In this study, we analyzed the effects of fiscal and monetary policy lags on economic stability. In Section 3, we examined the case of a monetary policy with a lag. We confirmed that the results of Asada and Yoshida [12] that examined the case of a fiscal policy with a lag also basically hold in our model; that is, policy lags may cause economic instability and suppress the effect of expeditious policies aimed at economic stability (a model with a fiscal policy that does not consider a policy lag is proposed by Asada [21]).

Moreover, in Section 4, we examined the case wherein both fiscal and monetary policy lags exist and demonstrated that, in the neighborhood of a stability crossing curve, a monetary policy lag can have a stabilizing effect.

According to Friedman [22], policy lags can generally be classified into three types: recognition, implementation, and diffusion lags. Unlike recognition and diffusion lags, implementation lag can be considered as purposefully adjustable to some extent. Therefore, this study suggests that an adjustment of the timing of policy implementation can be a means to achieve stabilization.

Appendix

Direction of Crossing

Differentiating (19) with respect to , we obtain or, equivalently,From (19), we can express as follows:

Substituting (A.3) into (A.2) and by evaluation at , we obtain The denominator of the right-hand side of this expression is positive. Thus, we only have to observe the sign of the numerator. The numerator is expanded as . Furthermore, using (26), it is rewritten as follows: As , we obtain .

Conflict of Interests

The author declares that there is no conflict of interests regarding the publication of this paper.

Acknowledgments

The author appreciates the helpful comments and suggestions received from an anonymous referee and Professors Akio Matsumoto and Toichiro Asada (Chuo University).