Abstract

In this paper, we combine the reduced-form model with the structural model to discuss the European vulnerable option pricing. We define that the default occurs when the default process jumps or the corporate goes bankrupt. Assuming that the underlying asset follows the jump-diffusion process and the default follows the Vasicek model, we can have the expression of European vulnerable option. Then we use the measure transformation and martingale method to derive the explicit solution of it.

1. Instruction

Vulnerable option is a kind of option with credit risk. The pricing of credit risk has been concerned by scholars for a long time. Merton (1974) [1] firstly introduced option pricing into zero coupon bond with credit risk. He assumed that the capital structure of corporate consisted of two parts which are assets and liabilities; the default occurred when the corporate was insolvent at maturity. This is the basic of structural model. Black and Cox (1976) [2] researched the corporate bond pricing with subordinated debt capital structure. They improved the definition of default and took the interest and dividend into consideration to obtain the corporate bond pricing. Johnson and Stulz (1987) [3] discussed the option pricing with credit risk based on the structural model and put forward the conception of vulnerable option firstly. Longstaff and Schwartz (1995) [4] assumed that the default boundary was a constant and the recovery rate was an exogenous ratio. Then they derived the zero coupon bond pricing. Hull and White (1995) [5] assumed that the underlying asset and the counterparty asset were independent of each other and derived the vulnerable option pricing. Jarrow and Turnbull (2000) [6] presented the reduced-form model. They considered that the occurrence of default was a kind of jumps and they used the Poisson process with constant intensity to describe the density of default. Rich (1996) [7] presented that the default could occur before maturity and the equity was exercised immediately if default occurred. Klein (1996) [8] supposed that the underlying assets and credit risk were correlated and deduced the option pricing with martingale method. Madan and Unal (1998) [9] put forward a model with stochastic default intensity. According to Lando (1998) [10], the default-free bond pricing method was used for default bond pricing by adjusting the short-term interest rate. Assuming that the default occurs at any time with specific probability, Duffie and Singleton (1999) [11] deduced the default bond pricing at initial time. Klein and Inglis (2001) [12] took the stochastic default boundary which depends on options and counterparty debts into consideration to discuss option pricing. Ammann (2002) [13] deduced the explicit solution of vulnerable option by using structural method on the assumptions of stochastic interest and boundary. The unexpected risks were introduced into default by Zhou (2001) [14]; he assumed that the corporate assets were composed of continuous process and jump process and presented the corporate assets value model based on the jump-diffusion process firstly. Hui et al. (2003) [15] discussed the pricing model with dynamic default boundary and derived the explicit solution of the vulnerable option by using the method of partial differential equation. Lakner and Liang (2008) [16] studied the credit default bonds pricing based on the structure model and the reduced-form model by using martingale method. Wang and Wang (2010) [17] assumed that the underlying asset followed the jump-diffusion process and derived the expression of the European vulnerable option pricing under the Markov regime switching model. Tchuindjo (2011) [18] studied the pricing of bond and bond option under the condition of stochastic default intensity and obtained the explicit solution. Su and Wang (2012) [19] assumed that the default intensity followed the stochastic model with jumps; then the vulnerable option pricing was given based on the reduced-form model by the martingale method. Wang et al. (2015) [20] deduced the explicit solution of the European vulnerable option which was derived by the fractional Brownian motion with jumps. Yoon and Kim (2015) [21] used double Mellin transforms to study European vulnerable options under constant as well as stochastic interest rates and obtained an analytic closed-form pricing formula in each interest rate case. Fard (2015) [22] obtained a closed-form price for the vulnerable option by using the Esscher transform under a completely random generalized jump-diffusion model. Wang (2016) [23] presented a pricing model which allows for the correlation between the intensity of default and the variance of the underlying asset and derived a closed-form solution for the vulnerable option. Lee et al. (2016) [24] studied the pricing of European-type vulnerable options when the underlying asset follows the Heston dynamics and obtained a closed-form analytic formula of the option price as a stochastic volatility extension of the classical Heston formula. Jeon et al. (2017) [25] studied the pricing of vulnerable path-dependent options using double Mellin transforms and obtained an explicit form pricing formula or semianalytic formula in each path-dependent option.

2. The European Vulnerable Option Pricing Model

Suppose that the uncertainty in the economy is described by the probability space where is a risk neutral martingale measure in which the discounted assets price is a martingale. The underlying assets and corporate assets are given bywhere , , and are constants and and are Brownian motions in the probability space. is a composite Poisson process and (set ) is the jump range of it. is a sequence of independent identically distributed random variables with the finite expected value and . , , , , and are independent of each other where is a Poisson process with parameter . Suppose that follows log-normal distribution, then we have .

Suppose that default intensity is -measurable in the space and it follows the Vasicek model in the risk neutral measurewhere , , and are all constants. The covariance matrix of , , and is

We will combine the reduced-form model with the structural model to discuss the European vulnerable option pricing. We define that the default occurs when the default process jumps or the corporate goes bankrupt. Suppose that the underlying asset follows the jump-diffusion process and the corporate asset follows the Brownian motion. Then we can have the European vulnerable option pricing at initial time in the risk neutral measure. We assume that the maturity is , the strike price is , the default time is , the proportion of bankruptcy costs in writer’s assets is , and the default boundary is a constant ; then the European vulnerable option pricing isSince is a filter space and , we have . Suppose that there is no default at initial time. According to the law of iterated expectations and theorem we have Since the path of is known at time , thenSo we have

3. The Explicit Solution of European Vulnerable Option Pricing

Suppose that the assets price follows the jump-diffusion process, then the measure transformation of the continuous diffusion process can be derived by Girsanov’s theorem and the measure transformation of the jump-diffusion process is given in Theorem 1.

Theorem 1. In the probability space , if one has Radon-Nikodym derivative where is a Poisson process with intensity and is a sequence of independent identically distributed random variables that the mean is and , then can be transformed into measure by where the intensity .

Proof. According to the definition of moment generating function, we have Since we haveLet ; thenSo in condition , the intensity of is .

Theorem 2. The European vulnerable option pricing at initial time in the risk neutral measure iswhere

Proof. For convenience, we define , whereThenThe derivation of , , and is separately shown in Proof , Proof , and Proof .
Proof I. We define , whereWe deduce firstly. We introduce a new measure According to (2)thenUsing (19) and Girsanov’s theorem, we haveAccording to (1)So in the measure , we haveSince and when , then we havewhereThen we will deduce . We introduce a new measureAccording to Girsanov’s theorem and Theorem 1So in measure Since we haveWhen whereProof II. We define , whereWe deduce firstly. We define an equivalent martingale measure according to Radon-Nikodym derivative as follows:According to (3)Let ; using Itô lemma we haveSoUsing Girsanov’s theorem, Then the solutions of and in measure are Since when , substituting and into , we havewhereThen we will deduce . We define a new measureLet ; according to (42)Then According to Girsanov’s theorem and Theorem 1So in measure, we haveSince when ,where Proof III. We define , whereWe deduce firstly. We introduce a new measureLet ; according to (43)SoAccording to Girsanov’s theorem, So, in measure , we haveSince when , we havewhere Then we will deduce . We introduce the measure as follows:Let ; according to (42) and (43)SoAccording to Girsanov’s theorem and Theorem 1So in measure Sincewhen , we havewhere

4. Numerical Experiments

In this section, we mainly discuss the influence of different parameters on option value. The parameters are as follows:

Figure 1 shows the influences of underlying assets and corporate assets on option value. We can see that the option value increases gradually with the increase of underlying assets and corporate assets, but the corporate assets have a higher influence on option value than that of underlying assets.

From Figure 2 we can see that the jump process has an obvious influence on option pricing which can make the option value more accurate. Because of the expansion of default, the default probability becomes higher. So the option value is lower than that in Black-Scholes model and this is coincident with the reality.

Figure 3 shows the changes of option value with different jump intensity. With the increase of jump intensity, the option value will decrease because of the rising default risk. We can choose the most suitable jump intensity according to the historical data to make the option value more accurate in reality.

From Figures 4 and 5 we can see that the option value decreases obviously when the default intensity and the default boundary are less than certain critical value while the it changes slowly when the default intensity and the default boundary exceed the critical value. In real application, the default intensity and the default boundary can be set according to the corporate reputation, so that the option pricing will be more reasonable.

Figure 6 shows that the option value and the proportion of bankruptcy costs are negatively correlated. The higher the bankruptcy costs, the lower the option value.

5. Conclusion

The traditional definition of default probability is divided into two forms: the reduced-form model says that the corporate will default as long as the jump occurs and the default probability is determined by the default intensity while the structural model says that the default occurs when the corporate assets are less than the default boundary and the default probability is determined by the relationship between corporate assets and default boundary. In this paper, we combine reduced-form model with structural model to discuss the European vulnerable option pricing. We define that the default occurs when the default process jumps or the corporate goes bankrupt. Supposing that the underlying asset follows the jump-diffusion process and the default follows the Vasicek model, we deduce the expression of vulnerable option. Then we use the measure transformation and martingale method to derive the explicit solution of it. The results show that the model we put forward is more in line with the real financial market.

Competing Interests

The authors declare that the mentioned received funding in Acknowledgments did not lead to any conflict of interests regarding the publication of this manuscript and there is no other possible conflict of interests in the manuscript.

Acknowledgments

This research is supported by NSFC (nos. 71371034; 71171051; 71201023), Teaching and Research Program for Excellent Young Teachers of Southeast University (no. 2242015R30021).