Abstract

This paper studies an investment-consumption problem under inflation. The consumption price level, the prices of the available assets, and the coefficient of the power utility are assumed to be sensitive to the states of underlying economy modulated by a continuous-time Markovian chain. The definition of admissible strategies and the verification theory corresponding to this stochastic control problem are presented. The analytical expression of the optimal investment strategy is derived. The existence, boundedness, and feasibility of the optimal consumption are proven. Finally, we analyze in detail by mathematical and numerical analysis how the risk aversion, the correlation coefficient between the inflation and the stock price, the inflation parameters, and the coefficient of utility affect the optimal investment and consumption strategy.

1. Introduction

The investment-consumption optimization problem has been one of the time-honored topics in which the decision-maker seeks to maximize the expected utility of intertemporal consumption plus the terminal wealth. The classical investment-consumption model can be traced back to the foundational work of Samuelson [1], Hakansson [2], Fama [3], and Merton [4]. Their foundational work has inspired various extensions and applications from different aspects in the past forty years, including Zariphopoulou [5], Akian et al. [6], Liu [7], Zhao and Nie [8], and Dai et al. [9] with transaction costs, Taksar and Sethi [10] and Zariphopoulou [11] with bankruptcy, Munk and Sørensen [12] and Wang and Yi [13] with stochastic interest rate or stochastic return rate, Munk [14] and Dybvig and Liu [15] with a stochastic income, and Pliska and Ye [16] and Kwak et al. [17] with a life insurance purchase.

No matter what the models are, the existing research papers mentioned above share the common setting that the investor makes the investment-consumption decision under the uncertainty of assets’ prices. However, the uncertainty of the assets’ prices also comes from the uncertainty of underlying economy. To be more specific, the market mode in a real world usually has a finite number of states, such as “bullish” and “bearish” and could switch among them. It is called “regime switching.” The empirical analysis shows that the returns of the assets, such as the stocks’ appreciation rates and volatility rates, are sensitive to the states of underlying economy and are quite different in different states. For example, Hardy [18] used monthly data from the Toronto Stock Exchange 300 indices and the Standard and Poor’s 500 to fit a regime-switching log-normal model and found that the regime-switching model is better than all the models considered. Usually the movement of the market states is depicted by a continuous-time finite-state Markovian chain and the asset’s return at time is assumed to be a function of the current market state. In the past years, there has been great interest of using regime-switching models in finance and actuarial science. Here we review the related literature with regime switching according to the research topic. Zhou and Yin [19], Çakmak and Özekici [20], Çelikyurt and Özekici [21], Wei and Ye [22], Wu and Li [23, 24], and Wu and Zeng [25] considered the optimal investment strategy under the mean-variance criterion while Chen et al. [26] investigated an asset-liability management problem. Cheung and Yang [27] and Çanakoğlu and Ozekici [28, 29] studied the investment policy under the power utility but the latter ones assumed that the utilities have the regime-dependent parameters; that is, the utility is being of the form . As for the optimal investment-consumption problem, Cheung and Yang [30] considered a multiperiod model where the return of the risky assets depends on the economic environments with an absorbing state which represents the bankruptcy state. Li et al. [31] and Zeng et al. [32] investigated a discrete-time investment-consumption problem with regime switching and uncertain time horizon. Gassiat et al. [33] studied this problem in an illiquid financial market where the asset trading has time restriction. Pirvu and Zhang [34] considered a continuous-time investment-consumption problem with regime-switching discount rate and asset returns. In this paper, enlightened by the existing literature, we assume that the utility function is of this form , where is dependent on the current market state . Under this assumption, the utility function is changed according to the market states over time. In this sense, our paper has adopted the similar assumption about the movement of the financial market and the utility parameters as some existing literature. For example, Çanakoğlu and Ozekici [28, 29] also assumed that the parameters of the power utility are state-dependent. However, there are some differences between our paper and the existing literature. Firstly, the optimization problem considered is different. Çanakoğlu and Ozekici [28, 29] investigated an optimal portfolio selection problem while our paper studies an investment-consumption strategy. Secondly, the above-mentioned research papers do not analyze the effects of the inflation. In contrast, in addition to the financial risk, the inflation risk is also considered in our paper.

In recent years, the phenomenon of inflation has been causing grave concern in developed and developing countries. When the continuous increase in price level exceeds a tolerable limit, the inflation can cause many distortions in investment behavior and effect greatly on daily life of the people. The persistence of inflation can diminish the investment enthusiasm on the normal financial products since the investors are not really earning money. They prefer acquisition of land and other assets which yield quick capital gains. When inflation continues over a period of time, it also erodes the motivation for saving due to the fact that the money is worth more presently than in the future. For example, if the return of the bank account was and the inflation was , then the real return on investment would be minus . In addition, when commodity price is raised, the consumers cannot buy as much as they could previously, and hence they have opted for major cuts in their daily budget. Nowadays, the problem of inflation is quite common for the people all over the world. Therefore, we think that it is theoretically and practically important to consider the investment-consumption problem under inflation.

However, none of the above papers allow for stochastic inflation. Here, we introduce some existing literature allowing for inflation. For the optimal portfolio selection problem under inflation, Brennan and Xia [35], Munk et al. [36], and Chiarella et al. [37] aimed to maximize the expected power utility from terminal real wealth and obtained the closed-form investment strategies for the investors. Menoncin [38] studied an optimal portfolio selection problem for a HARA utility investor under stochastic inflation and wage income. He obtained a quasiexplicit solution for this problem. Mamun and Visaltanachoti [39] analyzed numerically how the anticipated rate of inflation affected the investment strategy of US investors under the assumption that the assets available included treasury inflation protected securities, equity, real estate, treasury bonds, and corporate bonds. Their study indicated that when the anticipated rate of inflation is higher, the investor should allocate more wealth to the treasury inflation protected securities. For the defined contribution management problem under inflation, Battocchio and Menoncin [40] considered an optimal pension management under stochastic interest rate, wage income, and inflation. They wanted to maximize the expected exponential utility from terminal wealth and found a closed-form solution for this problem. Zhang and Ewald [41] assumed that the financial market consists of a money account, a stock, and an inflation linked bond. They wanted to maximize the expected power utility from the terminal wealth and obtained the optimal investment strategy using the martingale method. Han and Hung [42] assumed that the retired individual received a guarantee as a downside protection. The closed-form solution is obtained under the power utility function. For more information, refer to Battocchio and Menoncin [43], Zhang et al. [44], and de Jong [45]. For the optimal consumption problem under inflation, Brennan and Xia [35] investigated a problem for the interim consumption under the power utility and obtained the explicit expression of the consumption. Menoncin [46] generalized Menoncin [38] to the case with intertemporal consumption. He aimed to maximize the expected HARA utility of the intertemporal consumption plus the terminal wealth under the stochastic income and inflation and computed a quasiexplicit solution for both optimal consumption and investment. Chou et al. [47] considered an optimal portfolio-consumption problem under stochastic inflation with nominal and indexed bonds. They studied, respectively, an optimization problem that aims to maximize the expected terminal wealth at a fixed terminal time and an optimization problem that maximizes the intertemporal consumption utility with infinite time horizon. Paradiso et al. [48] studied the existence and stability of the consumption function in the United States of America since the 1950s. They introduced inflation as an additional explanatory variable to analyze the life-cycle consumption function.

We can see that literature on optimal investment-consumption under inflation is so limited. Moreover, the existing literature has not studied how the commodity price level affects the optimal investment-consumption decision of the investors in a Markovian regime-switching market as mentioned above. This paper aims to bridge the gap. Referring to Korn et al. [49], we assume that the instantaneous expected rate and volatility rate of inflation are also dependent on the market states.

The rest of our paper is organized as follows. The problem formulation and the verification theory are presented in Section 2. The explicit expressions of the investment strategy and consumption are obtained in Section 3. The properties of investment strategy are analyzed mathematically in Section 4. The properties of the optimal consumption proportion are demonstrated in Section 5 by mathematical and numerical analysis. This paper is concluded in Section 6.

2. Problem Formulation and Notations

In this paper, there are a bank account and a stock traded continuously within a time horizon whose price processes depend on the states of an underlying economy. Here the evolution of the market states is modulated by a continuous-time Markov chain taking discrete values in a finite space and having a generator . The price process of the bank account satisfies the following differential equation:where is the instantaneous interest rate of the bank account corresponding to the market state . The evolution of the price process of the stock is governed by the following Markovian regime-switching geometric Brownian motion:where is a standard one-dimensional Brownian motion and and are, respectively, the appreciation rate and volatility rate of the stock corresponding to the market state .

Let denote the nominal price level per unit of consumption goods at time . Then, the evolution of is assumed to follow the stochastic differential equation:where is a standard one-dimensional Brownian motion and and are the expected inflation rate and volatility rate at time , respectively. Generally, we assume that and are correlated with a correlation coefficient . Referring to Koo [50], (3) can be expressed aswhere is a standard one-dimensional Brownian motion independent of . Furthermore, we assume that and are independent of each other. To describe uncertainty, we employ a complete filtered probability space , where is defined as . We also assume throughout this paper that , , , , and are deterministic and uniformly bounded in for any given state .

Referring to Menoncin [46], the variable “represents the purchasing power of a nominal monetary unit. Furthermore, if we identify the value of a monetary unit with the number of goods that can be purchased against it, then can also be interpreted as the value of money.”

An investor joins the market at time with initial wealth and plans to invest and consume his wealth dynamically over a fixed time horizon . Let be the proportion of the wealth available invested in the stock at time and let be the real consumption, that is, the ratio between the nominal consumption and the price level . Then, the nominal wealth process satisfies the following stochastic differential equation:where .

Denote by the real wealth level at time after considering the inflation. Then according to Itô’s formula, the dynamics of iswith initial value .

The investor’s optimization problem could be described by the following:where is the discount rate and the set of admissible strategies is defined below. In our paper, the utility function is defined as , where , and .

Definition 1. A strategy is admissible if(i)for any initial wealth the stochastic differential equation (6) has a unique solution corresponding to ;(ii)the corresponding solution satisfies for all ;(iii), for all ;(iv) a.s.For convenience, denote by the set of admissible strategies .

We can write the value function in aswith terminal condition .

Then, the optimal investment-consumption problem can be formulated by the dynamic programming equationwhere and .

The optimality condition (9) is not sufficient if a verification theorem is not provided, so we present the verification theorem before we give the explicit solution to this problem. Let , where denote the set of all continuous functions that are continuously differentiable in and twice continuously differentiable in for any .

Theorem 2. Let , where , be a solution to the HJB equation (9) with boundary condition . If for all and all admissible controls there exists such thatthen we have (a);(b)if there exists an admissible strategy that is a maximizer of (9), then for all , , and . Furthermore, is an optimal strategy.

Proof. (a) Applying Itô’s formula to yieldsDenoteThus, we haveWe first assume that is bounded. When and and are admissible, according to Definition 1, we know thatare martingales, and . Since solves HJB equation (9), taking expectation on both sides of the above equality yieldswhich immediately implies that .
In the general case when might not be bounded, for a relatively fixed time , we definewhere satisfies and . Let be the first exit time of stochastic process from and . Then, is a sequence of stopping times. Furthermore, as , increases to with probability . Since now is bounded, referring to the analysis above, we can deriveEquation (10) implies uniform integrability of . Therefore, we havewhich implies that .
(b) When taking the strategy , the inequalities become equalities. Hence, conclusion (b) holds.

3. Optimal Investment-Consumption Strategy

In this section, we assume that the utility of the investor in state is given by the power utility functionwhere for all , , , and .

Suppose that a solution to HJB equation (9) is of this form:Then, substituting (20) into (9) yieldswhere is the partial derivative to .

If and , differentiating with respect to and in (21), respectively, gives the maximizers as follows:where solves the following equation:

Next we shall show that and the wealth process by the following lemmas step by step.

Lemma 3. If solves (24), then(a); furthermore, is uniformly bounded from below; that is, there exists a constant such that ;(b) is the only continuous solution of (24), and has an uniformly upper bound in .

Proof. (a) DenoteThen, in view of (24), we haveThe solution of the above equation is of this form:It is well known that is a martingale; then, we haveTo prove , we construct a Picard iterative sequence as follows:Noting that and , we haveSince all the coefficients in our paper are uniformly bounded, (32) indicates that for At the same time, it is well known that is the limit of the sequence as . Thus, , .
(b) For , denoteWe havewhich is a system of the first-order ordinary differential equations. Since is uniformly bounded for , satisfies thatfor suitable constants and . Moreover,Then,Therefore,which leads toNow it obvious that ’s satisfy Lipschitz condition. Consequently, (24) has a unique continuous solution denoted by in . A continuous function defined in a close interval must have an upper bound . If we define , we know that has a uniformly upper bound .

The next step is to prove that the stochastic differential equation (6) under in (22) and in (23) has a unique and nonnegative solution . The main results are presented in the following lemma.

Lemma 4. For any initial wealth , the stochastic differential equation (6) under and has a unique nonnegative solution . Furthermore,

Proof. Substituting (22) and (23) into (6) yieldswhereSince the coefficients of (41) are uniformly bounded, it is obvious that there exists a unique solution to (41) such asTherefore, for all .
Next, we shall prove that for . To this end, define , where is an -dimensional standard Brownian motion and is an column vector whose components are uniformly bounded in for any . For , we haveThe stochastic differential equation of is of this form:The uniformly bounded results in ; then, according to Krylov [51, p. 85], we have . It follows thatwhere is any column vector whose components are uniformly bounded in for any . In view of (43), for any given we haveIt follows (46) that .

Lemma 5. in (22) and in (23) are admissible and then are optimal strategies for the power utility model.

Proof. By Lemma 4, we know that conditions (i) and (ii) in Definition 1 hold and for all , which guarantees (iv) in Definition 1 holds. Since and are time deterministic and uniformly bounded functions for any given market state , holds naturally. By Lemma 4, we have Now we have verified that and are admissible and hence optimal for the power utility model.

The next work is to prove that the candidate value function in (20) satisfies all the conditions in Theorem 2. First of all, it is obvious that is a solution of (9). Moreover, for any and admissible control , there exists a such that

The detailed analysis above gives the main results of this paper presented in the following theorem.

Theorem 6. The optimal investment proportion and the optimal consumption for the power utility model are, respectively,where solves (24) and the value function is

4. Analysis of the Optimal Investment Proportion

First of all, if there is no inflation, by (50), the optimal investment proportion is which clearly shows that when the market state has higher expected return per unit risk or the investor has lower risk aversion, the investor would like to invest higher proportion of his wealth on the stock, which is a classical conclusion in the existing literature if the investor does not need to face the inflation.

However, when there is inflation, this conclusion may not hold. First, we can prove that the higher expected return per unit risk does not result in a higher investment proportion. By (50), the investment proportion is decreased by an amount of compared with the portfolio selection without inflation. This amount is increased with respect to the volatility rate of the inflation and the correlation coefficient . When , that is, the stock price and the inflation index are modulated by the same Brownian motion, the investment proportion is decreased by the largest amount. That means, if the stock and the commodity price level have the same volatility trend, the inflation volatility will diminish the investment proportion the most. Therefore, when the increasing range of the expected return per unit is lower than that of the inflation volatility, the investor would not buy more stocks and could even short sell the stock because he worries the high volatility of the inflation would seriously damage his investment return.

Next, we shall present the effects of the risk aversion on the investment proportion.

Lemma 7. When , the optimal investment proportion is increased with respect to the risk tolerance ; when , the optimal investment proportion is decreased with respect to the risk tolerance; when , the optimal investment proportion is a constant .

Proof. We rewrite (50) as it is clear that the conclusions of Lemma 7 hold.

Remark 8. When holds naturally. Therefore, the investment proportion increases as the risk tolerance increases, which reduces to a classical conclusion in the model without inflation.

Remark 9. When there is no inflation, the investment proportion is a positive number if . However, this conclusion does not hold in the case with inflation even if . When , that is, the risk tolerance is greater than leads to . By (50), . When , that is, the risk tolerance is less than cannot always guarantee a positive investment proportion if .

Remark 10. If , the investment proportion will decrease according to the risk tolerance. Moreover, if the risk tolerance is high enough, the investor will tend to short sell her/his stock, and the short selling proportion is increasing according to the risk tolerance.

5. Analysis of the Optimal Consumption Proportion

Denote bythe consumption proportion. Next, we shall analyze in detail the effects of the risk aversion, the correlation coefficient, the expected rate and volatility rate of the inflation index, and the utility coefficients on the consumption proportion. We assume that the risk-free return rate is a constant independent of time and market states, and the appreciation rate and volatility rate of the stock depend on the market states only. Let there be two market states, and , , , , the discount rate , the time horizon , and the generator

5.1. Effects of the Risk Aversion

In this subsection, assume that , , , and . We increase from to with step size . Then, the effects of risk aversion on the consumption proportion are obtained as demonstrated in Figure 1.

Figure 1 shows the following:(i)As , consumption proportion approaches , which is consistent with the conclusion in Cheung and Yang [30].(ii)As is increased from to some extent, the consumption proportion is raised accordingly. However, there come changes when continues to increase. The consumption proportions almost decrease to as increases to . Actually, since now , according to Lemma 7, an investor with higher risk tolerance will invest more of her/his wealth in the stock and consequently consume less of her/his wealth. That is, when is close to , the consumption proportion is almost zero in most cases.(iii)When is relatively small, the investor consumes a larger proportion of our wealth if it is closer to the end of the horizon. When is close to , that is, the risk tolerance is relatively high, the consumption rate decreases with time.

5.2. Effects of the Correlation Coefficients

Lemma 11. When is a constant in and , the consumption proportion is increasing according to the correlation coefficient if for all and .

Proof. By (25), we have If for all and , we know that decreases with respect to in , which has a consequence that in (26) decreases accordingly if increases for all . When , . Therefore, is an increasing function of . This together with the Picard sequence (31) indicates that decreases as decreases. Since is the limit of the Picard sequence, we immediately obtain that decreases as increases. Now it follows (55) that the conclusion in Lemma 11 holds.

Let and increase the correlation coefficient from to with step size 0.5 while keeping other parameters unchangeable. Since the minimal value of is , we can see clearly in Figure 2 that the consumption proportion at state 1 increases according to the increasing correlation coefficients. However, if we assume that , , and , then given that and . Therefore, we obtain Figure 3, which shows that the higher the is, the lower the consumption proportion is.

5.3. Effects of the Expected Inflation Rate

Lemma 12. The consumption proportion decreases if the expected inflation rate increases for all and when .

Proof. The proof of Lemma 12 is similar to that of Lemma 11, so it is omitted here.

Let and and increase respectively and from to with step size while keeping other parameters unchangeable; we obtain Figure 4. But if we change to be while keeping other parameters unchangeable, we obtain Figures 5 and 6.

Figures 46 show that if the risk aversion is greater than , then the higher the expected inflation rate is, the lower the consumption proportion is; otherwise, if the risk aversion is less than , the best decision for the investor is to consume a high proportion of her/his wealth at the current time when the expected inflation rate in the future is high no matter what the market state is.

5.4. Effects of the Inflation Volatility

Let , , and and increase from to with step size . The effects of the volatility of inflation on the consumption proportion are demonstrated in Figure 7. One can see that the higher the volatility rate is, the more the investor consumes. A similar phenomenon happens when we increase from to with step size while keeping . To explain this, we notice that in Figure 7, which has a consequence that the higher the volatility rate is, the lower the investment proportion is, by (50). Therefore, more wealth is used for personal consumption.

5.5. Effects of the Utility Coefficient

In this subsection, let , , , and and increase and from to with step size , respectively. Then, we have Figures 8 and 9.

Figures 8 and 9 present an interesting phenomenon that the increasing results in an increasing and a decreasing . Actually, we can regard as the attention degree of the consumption at state . Hence, a larger indicates that the investor cares more about the consumption utility at state and hence consumes a larger amount of her/his wealth. In contrast, the consumption proportion at other market states will be diminished correspondingly.

6. Conclusion

This paper considers a continuous-time investment-consumption problem under inflation where the stock price, the commodity price level, and the coefficient of the power utility all depend on the market states. The admissible strategy and verification theory corresponding to this problem are provided. We obtain the closed-form investment strategy and quasiexplicit consumption strategy by dynamic programming and stochastic control technique. By mathematical and numerical analysis, we obtain some interesting properties of the optimal strategies.

For the optimal strategy, (a) we say that a market has a better state if at this state the stock has a higher expected excess return per unit risk (the Sharpe ratio). Under the influence of the inflation, the investor would not always invest more wealth in the stock even if the market state is better. If the increasing range of the inflation volatility is higher than that of the Sharpe ratio of the stock, the investor would not invest more of his wealth on this stock since the high inflation erodes greatly the investment enthusiasm of the investor even if he is at a better market state; (b) if there is no inflation, then when the Sharpe ratio is greater than , an investor with higher risk aversion would invest less of his wealth in the stock. But if there exists inflation, the positive Sharpe ratio cannot guarantee this conclusion holding. Only if the Sharpe ratio is greater than the product of inflation volatility rate and correlation coefficient does the traditional conclusion hold; (c) the expected inflation rate and the utility coefficient have no impact on the optimal investment strategy.

For the optimal consumption strategy, (a) when the risk aversion is close to zero, the consumption proportion is almost zero. When the risk aversion is relatively small (big), the consumption proportion decreases (increases) with time; (b) when correlation coefficient is a constant in and the risk aversion is greater than , the consumption proportion is increasing according to the correlation coefficient if the Sharpe ratio of the stock is high enough; (c) when the risk aversion is greater than 1, the consumption proportion decreases according to an increasing expected inflation rate; (d) the higher the volatility rate of the inflation is, the higher the consumption proportion is; (e) a larger coefficient of utility results in a higher consumption proportion at state but a lower consumption proportion at state .

Although our model is rather general, it still deserves further extension as future research. For example, in most existing literature including our paper, only the coefficient of the utility depends on the market states, but the risk aversion is independent of the market state. So the future research may focus on the optimal investment-consumption problem with a state-dependent risk aversion.

Competing Interests

The author declares that they have no competing interests.

Acknowledgments

This research is supported by grants of the National Natural Science Foundation of China (no. 11301562), the Program for Innovation Research in Central University of Finance and Economics, and Beijing Social Science Foundation (no. 15JGB049).