Abstract

In the present paper, we derive analytical formulas for barrier and lookback options with underlying assets exposed to multiple defaults risks which include exogenous counterparty default risk and endogenous default risk. The endogenous default risk leads the asset price drop to zero and the exogenous counterparty default risk induces a drop in the asset price, but the asset can still be traded after this default time. An original technique is developed to valuate the barrier and lookback options by first conditioning on the predefault and the afterdefault time and then obtaining the unconditional analytic formulas for their price. We also compare the pricing results of our model with the default-free option model and exogenous counterparty default risk option model.

1. Introduction

Barrier and lookback options are among the most popular path-dependent derivatives traded in exchanges and over-the-counter markets worldwide. The barrier option is a financial derivative contract that is activated or deactivated when the price of the underlying asset crosses a certain level (called barrier) from above or below. And the standard floating lookback call (put) option confers the holder the right to buy (sell) an asset at its lowest (highest) price during the life of the contract. For a complete description of these and other related contracts, refer to Hull [1]. There has been extensive research in option pricing for path-dependent option. For example, Merton [2] and Goldman et al. [3] derive closed-form solutions for barrier and lookback options in the standard Black-Scholes model. Davydov and Linetsky [4] derive analytical formulas for the prices of path-dependent options, such as barrier and lookback options, with the asset price process under Constant Elasticity of Variance (CEV) diffusion model. Kou et al. [5] present analytical solutions for two-dimensional Laplace transforms of barrier option prices under a double exponential jump diffusion model.

Multiple defaults risks include exogenous counterparty default risk and endogenous default risk, where the exogenous counterparty default risk may not be unique. However, for simplicity, we assume that the exogenous counterparty default risk is sole in the following parts. In the financial market, an exogenous counterparty default usually has important influences in various contexts. In terms of credit spreads, one observes, in general, a positive jump of the default intensity which is called the contagious jump (see [6]). According to asset values for a firm, the default of a counterparty will in general induce a drop of its value process (refer to [7]). Jiao et al. analyze the impact of the single exogenous counterparty risk and the multiple exogenous counterparty risk on the optimal investment problem, we can refer to [8, 9] for more detail. In this paper, we study the impact of the multiple defaults risk on option pricing problem. In particular, we focus on the pricing of path-dependent option with the underlying asset subject to multiple defaults risk such that the instantaneous loss of the asset at the exogenous counterparty default time and the asset price instantaneously become zero at endogenous default time.

Ma et al., in [10], obtain that the explicit valuation of European options with the asset exposed to exogenous counterparty default risk. Yan derives analytical formulas for lookback and barrier options on underlying assets that are subject to an exogenous counterparty risk in [11]. The explicit pricing formulas for European option with asset exposed to multiple defaults risk is given by He [12]. However, to the best of our knowledge, the derivation of the analytic formula for pricing barrier and lookback options under the multiple defaults risk model has not been performed in the previous literature. The main difficultly lies in that the distribution of the first passage time is difficult to derive owing to the multiple defaults and the continuous trading of the underlying asset after the exogenous counterparty default time. We use the conditional density approach of default, which is particularly suitable to study what goes on after the default and was adopted by Jiao and Pham [8] for the optimal investment problem, to derive the explicit distribution of the first passage time and then obtain the analytic formulas for valuation of the barrier and lookback options. We also compare the pricing results of the multiple defaults risk model with Merton’s [2] default-free option model and Yan’s [11] exogenous counterparty default risk option model.

The organization of the rest of this paper is as follows. First, a financial model is introduced in Section 2. Next, an analytical formula for barrier option on underlying asset that can be exposed to multiple defaults risk is derived in Section 3. Then, in Section 4 we derive the formula for pricing lookback options under this model. Finally, we conclude the paper in final Section.

2. Financial Model

In this section, we consider a financial market model with a risk asset (stock) subject to multiple defaults risks. We denote the stock by , the dynamic of the stock is affected by not only the possibility of the exogenous counterparty default but also the possibility of the endogenous default. However, this stock still exists and can be traded after the exogenous counterparty default.

Assume is a complete probability space satisfying the usual conditions. Let be a Brownian motion with horizon on the probability space and denote by the natural filtration of . Let and be both, almost surely, nonnegative random variables on , representing the stock of the exogenous counterparty default time and the endogenous default time, respectively. Then, is defined by , where , which equals 0 if and 1 otherwise. Similar, is defined by , where . Denote and , then the progressively enlarged filtration , representing the structure of information available for the investors over . The market model is given by the following stochastic differential equation (SDE):where , , and are -predictable processes. and are the drift rate and volatility rate of the stock S, respectively, and is the (percentage) loss on the stock price induced by the defaults of the counterparty. At default time , the stock price S is reduced by a percentage of . However, the stock price S falls to zero at default time .

Let us define the following (mutually exclusive and exhaustive) events ordering the default times:

Then, according to Pham [13], the dynamic of stock price process (1) can be decomposed to the following four situations under physical measure:Situation 1: if the stock is in absence of any default in the life of the option, i.e., the default times satisfy , then we haveSituation 2: if the default times satisfy , then we haveSituation 3: if the stock has only exogenous counterparty default in the life of the option, i.e., the default times satisfy E, then we obtainSituation 4: if the stock has both endogenous default and exogenous counterparty default in the life of the option and the exogenous default time is early than the endogenous default time, i.e., the default times satisfy F, then we obtainwhere are -adapted process and are -measurable functions for all . When the counterparty default, the drift, and volatility coefficient of the stock price switch from to , the after default coefficients may depend on the default time . However, when the stock itself default, the drift and diffusion coefficient of the stock price switch from to due to the stock price identically vanishing. Here, for simplicity we assume that with are nonnegative constants and the distribution of fixed. Moreover , and are independent and are all the exponential variables with parameter , respectively. For more details refer to Jiao and Pham [8].

Assume that r is a risk-free interest rate and denote . Let us define the -adapted process:

By assuming , we define a probability measure which is equivalent to on with Radon–Nikodym density:under which, by Girsanov’s theorem, is a -Brownian motion. And thus we can rewrite (1) as follows:that is, by changing measure, the four situations to decompose of the stock price under the physical measure can be transformed into the corresponding following four forms under the equivalent martingale measure :Situation I: if the stock is in absence of any default in the life of the option, i.e., the default times satisfy , then we haveSituation II: if the default times satisfy , then we obtainSituation III: if the stock has only exogenous counterparty default in the life of the option, i.e., the default times satisfy E, then we haveSituation IV: if the stock has both endogenous default and exogenous counterparty default in the life of the option and the exogenous default time is early than the endogenous default time, i.e., the default times satisfy F, then we obtain

In practice, we may assume γ is a discrete random variable to simplify the computation; in what follows, we further assume that γ takes value with probability for , where (loss), (no change), and (gain).

3. Analytic Formula for Pricing Barrier Options

In this section we derive an analytic formula for pricing barrier options under the model (1). The barrier options include up-and-out, up-and-in, down-and-out, and down-and-in puts and calls. Since the approaches for deriving the formulas for pricing these kinds of barrier options are similar, we only study the up-and-out barrier call in this section.

Consider an up-and-out barrier call option expiring at time T, with strike price K and barrier level B. We assume that and denote the maximum of the stock price up time to T by

Then, the option knocks out (i.e., payoff equals to 0) if and only if , on the other hand, the option pay off is when . In other words, the payoff of the option is

Thus, the risk-neutral price of the up-and-out barrier call option at initial time is

According to compute (17), we obtain the risk-neutral price of the up-and-out barrier call option at time 0 under multiple defaults risks model as follows.

Theorem 1. If , then the risk-neutral price of an up-and-out barrier call option at time 0 under model (1) is given bywhere is the standard normal distribution function andwith

Proof. See Appendix A.

Remark 1. (1)If , i.e., there is no exist endogenous default risk in model (1), then the risk-neutral price of the up-and-out barrier call option at time 0 under this model becomeswherewithIt is obvious that the value of up-and-out barrier call option at time 0 under model (1) is the same as the one at time 0 with the stock exposed to counterparty risk (see Yan [11]).(2)If and , i.e., there is no any default in model (1), then the risk-neutral price of up-and-out barrier call option at time 0 under this model becomeswith . It is obvious that (24) is standard Black–Scholes formula for up-and-out call option.

4. Analytic Formula for Pricing Lookback Options

In this section, we price a floating strike lookback option, whose payoff is the difference between the maximum asset price over the life time and the asset price at expiration.

By formula (15), the risk-neutral price of the lookback option at initial time can be written as follows:

According to the calculation of (25), we obtain the following theorem.

Theorem 2. The risk-neutral price of the lookback option at initial time under model (1) is given bywherewith

Proof. See Appendix B.

Remark 2. (1)If , i.e., there is no exist endogenous default risk in model (1), then the risk-neutral price of the lookback option at time 0 under this model becomeswherewithIt is obvious that the value of lookback option at time 0 under model (1) is the same as the one at time 0 with the stock exposed to counterparty risk (see Yan [11]).(2)If and , i.e., there is no any default in model (1), then the risk-neutral price of lookback option at time 0 under this model becomes with . It is obvious that (32) is standard Black–Scholes formula for lookback option.

5. Conclusions

The explicit analytical formulas for European call and put options with asset exposed to multiple defaults risks have been derived. However, it is still very challenging to obtain the explicit analytical formulas for path-dependent options under this model. This is because the multiple default risks cause the difficultly in deriving the density of the first passage time for the maximum asset price. In this paper, the conditional density approach, which is developed by Jiao and Pham [8] for optimal investment, is utilized to overcome the difficulty and derive the formulas for lookback and barrier options when the underlying asset is subject to multiple defaults risks. Future research lies in deriving analytic formulas for the path-dependent options with two underlying assets exposed to loop contagion risks.

Appendix

A. Proof of Theorem 1

We can rewrite (17) as follows:

If the default times satisfy situation I, then the dynamic of stock price process takes the form as (11). By Ito’s lemma and (11), we can obtainwhere with .

We define , so by (15) we derive that

The first term on the right-hand side of (A.1) can be calculated as

Notice that corresponds to the case when there is no any default. Then, we use the following identity:and a similar technique as in [14], can be calculated as where is defined in Theorem 1.

If the stock has endogenous default in the life of the option, i.e., the default time satisfy situation II and situation IV, then the price of the stock at expiration T is zero, and thus we obtain . Therefore, the second term on the right-hand side of (A.1) is equal to 0.

If the default times satisfy situation III, then the dynamic of stock price process such that (13). Using Ito’s lemma, the solution to SDE (13) for the stock price iswhere and . Denote and , then we have

It is obvious that and are independent on . Let , we calculatewhere and .

Notice that the expectationcorresponds to the case when there is no default. Therefore using the techniques as in calculate (A.6), we havewhere are defined in Theorem 1.

Then, the third term on the right-hand side of (A.1) can be calculated as follows:

According to Shreve [14], the joint density function under of involved with and is

Substituting (A.11) and into (A.9) and using (A.13), we can continue to calculate (A.12) and obtainwhere is defined in Theorem 1. Combining (A.6) and (A.14), we obtain formula (18). Thus, the proof of Theorem 1 is complete.

B. Proof of Theorem 2

The risk-neutral price of the lookback option (25) can be rewritten as

According to [12], the distribution function of the stock price at expire time T is given bywith and . Combining the distribution function F in (B.2) and the following identitythe second term on the right-hand side of (B.1) can be calculated as follows:where we use and to obtain the last equality in formula (B.4).

Next we aim to calculate the first term on the right-hand side of (B.1):

If the default times satisfy situation I, then by (11) and Ito’s lemma, we can obtain (A.2) and (A.3). Thus, the first term of the right-hand side of (B.5) can be calculated as

According to Shreve [14], the density function of under is given byso we haveand thus the value of the expectation in (B.6) can be calculated as follows:

Similar, the second term of the right-hand side of (B.5) can be calculated as

We shall calculate the third term of the right-hand side of (B.5). To this end, we define

By define of the , we have

According to Shreve [14], we obtain

Then, combining (B.11) and (B.13), the first term of the right-hand side of (B.12) can be calculated asand we use some technique in calculated integral to obtain that the second term of the right-hand side of (B.12) iswhere

Substituting (B.14) and (B.15) into (B.12), we have

By the independence lemma (refer to [14]), we have

If the default times satisfy situation III, then by (13) and Ito’s lemma, we can obtain (A.7) and (A.8). Thus, the third term of the right-hand side of (B.5) can be calculated as

Substituting (B.17) and (B.18) into (B.19) and using (A.13), we obtain that

Similar, the last term of the right-hand side of (B.5) can be calculated aswhere and are defined in Theorem 2. Combining (B.9), (B.10), (B.20), and (B.21) gives the value of , and then using (B.4) complete the proof of this theorem.

Data Availability

No data were used to support this study.

Conflicts of Interest

The author declares that there are no conflicts of interest regarding the publication of this paper.

Acknowledgments

This work was supported by the First-Class Subjects of Mathematics (Grant No. xkdm0701) and the Innovative Team Program of the Neijiang Normal University (Grant No. 2019TD02).