Abstract

This paper aims to study option pricing problem under the subordinated Brownian motion. Firstly, we prove that the subordinated Brownian motion controlled by the fractional diffusion equation has many financial properties, such as self-similarity, leptokurtic, and long memory, which indicate that the fractional calculus can describe the financial data well. Then, we investigate the option pricing under the assumption that the stock price is driven by the subordinated Brownian motion. The closed-form pricing formula for European options is derived. In the comparison with the classic Black–Sholes model, we find the option prices become higher, and the “volatility smiles” phenomenon happens in the proposed model. Finally, an empirical analysis is performed to show the validity of these results.

1. Introduction

Brownian motion and normal distribution have been widely used in the Black–Scholes option pricing framework to the return of assets. The classical Black–Scholes model is based on the diffusion process called geometric Brownian motion (GBM) [1, 2].where are constants and is the standard Brownian motion.

However, on the one hand, in the last few years, the empirical studies have shown that many characteristic properties of markets cannot be captured by the BS model [3], such as heavy tailed, long-range correlations, and lack of scale invariance and periods of constant values [4].

On the other hand, in a complete financial market without transaction costs, the Black–Scholes no-arbitrage argument provides a hedging portfolio that replicates the option. However, the Black–Scholes hedging portfolio requires continuous trading, and therefore, in a market with propositional transaction costs, it is expensive. Leland [5] first examined option replication in the presence of transaction costs (TC) in a discrete time setting and posed a modified replicating strategy, which depends upon the level of transactions costs and upon the revision interval, as well as upon the option to be replicated and the environment. Since then, a lot of authors study this problem, all in a discrete time setting [6, 7].

Notably, in a variety of cases, GBM has failed to reproduce the properties of real asset prices. For instance, by definition, GBM is not able to adequately reproduce fat-tailed distributions of various characteristics observed in reality. In the paper [8], Magdziarz applied the subdiffusive mechanism of trapping events to describe properly financial data exhibiting periods of constant values and introduced the subdiffusive geometric Brownian motion (SGBM) as the model of asset prices exhibiting subdiffusive dynamics. Here, the parent process is the GBM given by equation (1), and is the inverse time -stable subordinator with the parameter , which can be expressed aswhere is a strictly increasing -stable process with Laplace transform given by , and is independent of . Magdziarz showed that the considered model is arbitrage-free but incomplete since the equivalent martingale measure is not unique. But, under a special equivalent martingale measure, they obtained the corresponding subdiffusive BS formula for the fair prices of European options. In [9, 10], Magdziarz extend the -stable subordinator to a more general subordinator, and the corresponding BS formula is also obtained. This subdiffusive approach assumes anomalous price dynamics. Concretely, the observation that the distribution of log returns is fat-tailed can be attributed to prolonged periods, in which the price of the asset exhibits approximately constant extreme values. These constant periods can be considered to be trapping of particles, as is done in physical systems that manifest anomalous diffusion (subdiffusion) [1113]. The correlated continuous time random walk is also employed to describe the stock price, and the option pricing formula is obtained in [14]. In [15, 16], Aguilar showed that the price of an European call option, whose underlying asset price is driven by the space-time fractional diffusion, can be expressed in terms of rapidly convergent double-series. The stock is supposed to be driven by Levy processes in [1719], but the variance of this process does not exist.

Since, in financial market, the expected return is linearly correlative to time and the variance exists. So, in this paper, we suppose that the underlying of the option contract is driven by a subordinated Brownian motion, i.e., the price of underlying follows the stochastic differential equation:

Here, we suppose the underling pays no dividends.

The paper is organized as follows. In Section 2, we study the self-similarity, leptokurtic, and long memory features of the subordinated geometric Brownian motion, which imply that the supposed model is suitable to describe the asset price. In Section 3, we apply this model to option pricing problem. The closed form representation of the option pricing formula is derived. In Section 4, we present our conclusions.

2. The Subordinated Brownian Motion

In this section, we will study the properties of the subordinated geometric Brownian motion (4) to justify our hypothesis.

Firstly, since the strictly increasing -stable process is self-similar, it is not difficult to prove that the inverse time is self-similar by its definition (3). The independence between and leads to be self-similar. The self-similarity is a quite important property in financial market [20].

Secondly, the probability density function of volatility term has been proved to satisfy the following fractional diffusion equation [21]:with initial condition . Here, the fractional derivative is also the Caputo type. This equation was first derived from the continuous-time random walk scheme with heavy-tailed waiting-times [22]. It was proved to be subdiffusive (). Subdiffusion is a well-known and established phenomenon in statistical physics. The usual model of subdiffusion in physics is developed in terms of FFPE (fractional Fokker–Planck equations). It provides a useful way for the description of transport dynamics in complex systems [21]. The empirical data indicate the subdiffusive nature exits in the short rate dynamics [23].

In [22], the authors studied the asymptotic behavior of the solution of the fractional diffusion equation. They found , where , , which means the solution follows a stretched Gaussian distribution. In other words, the solution for equation (4) has heavy tail and high peak, in contrast to the normal distribution. In [24], we can find the figure of the solution, and the simulated results can be found in [25]. The heavy tail and high peak phenomenon (always called leptokurtic feature) is quite common in the financial historical data [4, 26], such as the return risk of the assets. Fractional calculus has become a useful tool to fit the financial data [2730].

From the definition of , we know that, for every jump of , there is a corresponding flat period of its inverse . These heavy-tailed flat periods of represent long waiting-times in which the subdiffusive particle gets immobilized in the trap (see Figure 1). When reduces to the “objective time” t.

Thirdly, as we know, the PDF of follows the fractional diffusion equation, where the Caputo fractional operator is given as

From the definition of Caputo fractional derivative, we know the fractional derivative at time is not defined locally, and it relies on the total effects of the commonly used first-order integer derivative on the interval . So, it can be used to describe the variation of a system in which the instantaneous change rate depends on the past state, which is called memory effect. Because of the kernel function , the process turns out to be a long-memory processes, namely, non-Markovian processes characterized by a memory function exhibiting a power-law time decay [28]. However, there is substantial evidence that long memory processes describe rather well-financial data such as forward premiums, interest rate differentials, and inflation rates. Perhaps, the most dramatic empirical success of long memory processes has been in recent work on modeling the volatility of asset prices and power transformations of returns[31].

In addition, let be the return of the stock in the period of time , defined by . In discrete time, equation (3) turns to

Then, the expected return of the stock , which is linearly correlative to time. But the expected return turns to in [8].

The scaling role is also satisfied by ,which implies is a multifractal process [32]. So, it is a useful tool to characterize asset returns feature.

In summary, the stochastic differential equation (3) presents many important financial properties, such as self-similarity, leptokurtic feature, and long memory. So, we assert that model equation (3) characterizes the price of underlying well. In Section 3, we investigate the option pricing problem under the assumption that the underlying of the option contract is driven by the time changed Brownian motion.

3. Option Pricing under the Subordinated Models

Let be the value at time of an European option on the above underlying with expiration data and exercise price and the boundary condition

Since is independent of , then the subordinated geometric Brownian motion (4) can be seen as a geometric Brownian motion with stochastic volatilitywhere is a stochastic process driven by . The well-known option pricing problem with stochastic volatility can be found in [33]. Let , then . The relation can also be given aswhere is the increasing process, so the stochastic integral with respect to can be defined as Riemann integral. And, is independent of , and then is also independent of . By using Itô theory, equation (3) yields

We can get the log distribution of which is no longer the normal distribution, but yields towhere is the probability density function of , given as (see [34]). By using the properties of , we also can get the meanand the second moment

Then, we can get the variance of , given as

The results reduce to the ones showed in [35] as . The second moment does not exist when the stock price is driven by Levy process [36].

Here, we cannot build a portfolio to hedge the two stochastic terms and . So, the self-financing method used in the classical Black–Sholes model is not suitable for this model, and under hypothesis (4), the market is incomplete.

Now, let , where is the risk-free rate, so denotes the discounted value of the risk assets, then

Let

Then, equation (16) yields

Here, let be the probability measure defined aswhere and

By Girsanov theory [37], we know is Brownian motion under the probability measure . So, the discounted value is the -martingale with respect to . Here, denotes the information about the history of asset prices up to time , dependent on the stochastic process . is also called filtration and is interpreted as the background information which is available for the investor. The more time it proceeds, the more the information is revealed to the investor. Then, the price of the European option is given bywhere is given by equation (8), and under the new measure , the asset price yields

On the one hand, according to the option pricing formula (21), we know that the option price depends on the information filtration , which is random, so is the option price . They are both dependent on stochastic term . In fact, in the real market, each people get his price of option based on the obtained information. The information people received are different, which leads them to price their options differently, which is consistent with the option pricing formula (21). So, the option price is not unique, which implies the market is incomplete. On the other hand, the stochastic volatility leads to the equivalent martingale is not unique, so the arbitrage opportunity exists and we cannot get the unique price of option under our assumption. All these results are caused by the randomness of .

Form the option pricing formula (21), we know the option price cannot be easily calculated, which is dependent on the catched information , and the randomness of leads to the nonuniqueness of option price. However, for t = 0, is no longer stochastic, but fixed, . At , the catched information is zero for everyone, and they are equal in the market. So, the option price is unique, and the market is complete at that moment. We should notice that the martingale measure has one important advantage. When , reduces to and reduces to the martingale measure of the classical BS model, which is known to be arbitrage-free and complete [8]. Thus, in the following, we concentrate on the martingale measure and deduce the analytical option pricing formula.

When , the option pricing formula (21) yields to

Here, we consider the European option, Call; then,where is the indicator function. Here,where is the cumulative function of normal distribution and . We also can getwhere . So, we have

Here, . We should notice that as ; then, the option pricing formula equation (27) reduces to the classical Black–Sholes model [1, 2]. The results are consistent with those obtained in [15, 38] when the order of space fractional derivative reduces to 2.

The model tells us the option price is fair (or unique) when it is firstly written. The reason lies in the information about this option obtained by the straddle both sides are zero at that moment. After that, different people will get different information about this option from market, which leads to the different price. Then, trading between different people happens. The more information obtained, the more accurate the price is. From the definition of , we know , for , then , which indicates people can only capture part of the information that matches the real market. For , each person can capture all the information about the option, which implies this is a perfect market. So, the investors will get the same price for the option, there is no arbitrage in the market. But, in real world, different people set the different reasonable price of option based on the information they captured, which makes options market actively traded.

By comparing this obtained formula with the classical Black–Sholes pricing formula in Figure 2, we find that the call option price increases with the decrease of . In the real world, the option is an insurance product, which is used to hedge the risk of the underlying assets. As the return of the underlying assets is supposed to be heavy tailed, the risk is redistributed, which results in an adjustment of the option price. The risk increases with the decrease of the parameter which leads to the higher option price, especially the strike price is near the expectation of . This behavior can be observed in situations when we face some kind of unexpected or sudden change of regime, such as a black day on the market, the bankruptcy of a company trading on the market, and a natural disaster [39]. Such sudden change also can be modeled by considering GBM with resetting [40, 41]. In short time, people are willing to spend more money to protect their assets.

As we know, if the Black–Scholes model is completely correct, then the implied volatility should be constant. In reality, it is widely recognized that the implied volatility curve resembles a “smile,” meaning it is a convex curve of the strike price. This empirical phenomenon called “volatility smile” in option markets [42]. The implied volatility can be obtained by two steps: step one, use option pricing formula (27) to get the option price. Step two, use the obtained option price to derive the volatility by the classical Black–Sholes formula. By following the above two steps, we obtain the implied volatility smile with different . From Figure 3, we find the smaller the parameter is, the larger the curvature is. The volatility tends to be horizontal as . Moreover, following the same procedure, we can deduce that the option price will be lower than the classical one if the parameters , and the volatility will be concave, which is called “volatility cry.”

We choose SPDR S&P500 ETF call option (SPY) as the empirical research object. The quotation data is April 7, 2021, and the expiration date is April 18, 2021. The index of S&P500 ETF is 406.12 (source: https://yahoo.com). Here, we imply the rescaled range analysis method (R/S analysis method) to estimate the parameter , which yields . In Figure 4, we find the proposed option price is higher than the classical Black–Scholes price and closer to the real price.

4. Conclusions

In this paper, we employ a time changed Brownian motion, whose PDF is proved to follow the fractional diffusion equation. The process exhibits many financial characters, such as self-similarity, leptokurtic, and long memory features. Then, we apply this model to the option pricing problem. The underlying of the option contract is supposed to be driven by a subordinated geometric Brownian motion. Under this assumption, we obtain the evaluation formula of an European option. In contrast with the classical model, higher option price and “volatility smile” are found in our model. These phenomenon is consistent with the real market. An empirical analysis is also made to show the accuracy of our model. Recently, the empirical results indicate the rough stochastic volatility model can capture the real market well. How will the option price be if the rough stochastic volatility is driven by , which is interesting research contents. Study on the time averaged MSD and nonergodicity of this subordinated geometric Brownian motion is also meaningful [40, 43, 44]. Finally, we expect that the results obtained here may be useful to the discussion of the anomalous diffusion systems and complex financial market [45, 46].

Data Availability

The data used to support the findings of this study are included within the article.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare that no conflicts of interest exist regarding this manuscript.

Acknowledgments

This work was supported by the Subject of Philosophy and Social Science Planning in Zhejiang Province (no. 21NDJC168YB) and National Natural Science Foundation of China (no. 11801288).