Abstract

We investigate the stochastic dynamics of bank liquidity parameters such as liquid assets and nett cash outflow in relation to the global financial crisis. These parameters enable us to determine the liquidity coverage ratio that is one of the metrics used in ratio analysis to measure bank liquidity. In this regard, numerical results show that bank behavior related to liquidity was highly procyclical during the financial crisis. We also consider a theoretical-quantitative approach to bank liquidity provisioning. In this case, we provide an explicit expression for the aggregate liquidity risk when a locally risk-minimizing strategy is utilized.

1. Introduction

During the global financial crisis (GFC), banks were under severe pressure to maintain adequate liquidity. In general, empirical evidence shows that banks with sufficient liquidity can meet their payment obligations while banks with low liquidity cannot. The GFC highlighted the fact that liquidity risk can proliferate quickly with funding sources dissipating and concerns about asset valuation and capital adequacy realizing. This situation underscores the important relationship between funding risk (involving raising funds to bankroll asset holdings) and market liquidity (involving the efficient conversion of assets into liquid funds at a given price). In response to this, the Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (BCBS) is attempting to develop an international framework for liquidity risk measurement, standards, and monitoring (see, e.g., [1]). Although pre-Basel III regulation establishes procedures for assessing credit, market, and operational risk, it does not provide effective protocols for managing liquidity and systemic risks. The drafting of Basel III represents an effort to address the latter (see, e.g., [2โ€“4]).

Current liquidity risk management procedures can be classified as micro- or macroprudential. In the case of the former, simple liquidity ratios such as credit-to-deposit ratios (nett stable funding ratios), liquidity coverage ratios and the assessment of the gap between short-term liabilities and assets are appropriate to cover the objectives of bank balance sheet analysis. The ratio approach for liquidity risk management is a quantitative international accepted standard for alerting banks about any possible adverse economic downturns. For instance, the credit-to-deposit ratio assesses the relationships between sources and uses of funds held in the bankโ€™s portfolio but has limitations which ultimately do not reflect information on market financing with short-term maturity. By contrast, the liquidity coverage ratio (LCR) performs better by ensuring the coverage of some of the immediate liabilities. Since the LCR depends only on bank balance sheet data, it does not take into account the residual maturities on various uses and sources of funds. Also, in a global context, a quantitative approach may not take financial market conditions into account. In this case, a more comprehensive characterization of the bank systemโ€™s liquidity risk through designed stress testing and constructed contingency plans is considered. The Basel Committee on Banking Supervision suggested best practices related to international liquidity standards. In this case, a well-designed policy monitoring instrument to measure and regulate the dynamics of foreign currency is considered to best take financial market conditions into account. Also, central banks (CBs) have a pivotal role to play in managing liquidity inflows via macroeconomic management of exchange rate and interest rate responses. The modeling of capital markets as well as stock and bond behavior also contribute to the liquidity response for possible stress conditions observed. The above approaches for liquidity analysis take into account the macroprudential liquidity management of banks.

In this paper, in Section 2, we discuss balance sheet items related to liquid assets and nett cash outflow in order to build a stochastic LCR model. Before the GFC, banks were prosperous with high LCRs, high cash inflows, low interest rates, and low nett cash outflows. This was followed by the collapse of liquidity, exploding default rates, and the effects thereof during the GFC. Next, in Section 3, we apply a dynamic provisioning strategy to liquidity risk management. In this case, we address the problem of dynamic liquidity provisioning for a mortgage, ฮ›, which is an underlying (illiquid) nonmarketable asset, by substituting (liquid) marketable securities, ๐‘†. In the light of the above, banks prefer to trade in a Treasury bond market because of liquidity reasons. Since the loan process (ฮ›๐‘ก)0โ‰ค๐‘กโ‰ค๐‘‡ is not completely correlated with the substitute, it creates the market incompleteness. In other words, we will employ non-self-financing strategy to replicate the trading process. Therefore the banks would require that the uncertainty involved over the remaining of the trading period be minimized. In this case, we specifically minimize at each date, the uncertainty over the next infinitesimal period. In the dynamics trading there is always a residual risk emanating from the imperfection of the correlation between the Brownian motions. Due to the no-arbitrage opportunities there are infinitely many equivalent martingale measures so that pricing is directly linked to risk. Therefore, we choose a pricing candidate (equivalent martingale measure) under which the discounted stock price follows a martingale. This equivalent measure is chosen according to a provisioning strategy which ensures that the value of ฮ› is the value of the replicating portfolio. We also provide a framework for assessing residual aggregate liquidity risk stemming from the application of the above strategy.

1.1. Literature Review

The documents formulated in response to the proposed Basel III regulatory framework are among the most topical literature on bank liquidity (see, e.g., [1]). During the GFC, unprecedented levels of liquidity support were required from CBs in order to sustain the financial system and even with such extensive support a number of banks failed, were forced into mergers, or required resolution. The crisis illustrated how quickly and severely liquidity risks can crystallize and certain sources of funding can evaporate, compounding concerns related to the valuation of assets and capital adequacy (see, e.g., [2โ€“4]). A key characteristic of the GFC was the inaccurate and ineffective management of liquidity risk. In recognition of the need for banks to improve their liquidity risk management and control their exposures to such risk, the BCBS issued Principles for Sound Liquidity Risk Management and Supervision in September 2008 (see, e.g., [1]). Supervisors are expected to assess both the adequacy of a bankโ€™s liquidity risk management framework and its liquidity risk exposure. In addition, they are required to take prompt action to address the banks risk management deficiencies or excess exposure in order to protect depositors and enhance the overall stability of the financial system. To reinforce these supervisory objectives and efforts, the BCBS has recently focussed on further elevating the resilience of internationally active banks to liquidity stresses across the globe, as well as increasing international harmonization of liquidity risk supervision (see, e.g., [1]). The BCBS hopes to develop internationally consistent regulatory standards for liquidity risk supervision as a cornerstone of a global framework to strengthen liquidity risk management and supervision (see, e.g., [2โ€“4]).

In [5] it is asserted that bank liquidity behavior can be described by straightforward indicators constructed from firm-specific balance sheet data (see, also, [6, 7]). Also, their analysis underscores the relevance of using several indicators of liquidity risk at the same time, given the different leads and lags of the measures with systemic risk. Our study is related to theirs in that we make use of balance sheet items to determine bank behavior. Another similarity is that we make use of data from [6] to formulate conclusions in a numerical quantitative framework (compare with the analysis in Section 3 below).

The contribution [8] studies the role of securitization in bank management. A new index of โ€œbank loan portfolio liquidityโ€ which can be thought of as a weighted average of the potential to securitize loans of a given type, where the weights reflect the composition of a bank loan portfolio. The paper uses this new index to show that by allowing banks to convert illiquid loans into liquid funds, securitization reduces banks holdings of liquid securities and increases their lending ability. Furthermore, securitization provides banks with an additional source of funding and makes bank lending less sensitive to cost of funds shocks. By extension, the securitization weakens the ability of regulators to affect banks lending activity but makes banks more susceptible to liquidity and funding crisis when the securitization market is shutdown. We conduct a similar analysis in Section 4 of this paper where illiquid underlying loans are substituted by liquid marketable securities.

In [9], we use actuarial methods to solve a nonlinear stochastic optimal liquidity risk management problem for subprime originators with deposit inflow rates and marketable securities allocation as controls (see [10]). The main objective is to minimize liquidity risk in the form of funding and credit crunch risk in an incomplete market. In order to accomplish this, we construct a stochastic model that incorporates originator mortgage and deposit reference processes. Finally, numerical examples that illustrate the main modeling and optimization features of the paper are provided. Our work in this paper also has a connection with [9] in that the nexus between funding risk and market liquidity is explored. However, this paper is an improvement on the aforementioned in that bank balance sheet features play a more prominent role (see, Sections 2, 3, and 4).

1.2. Main Questions and Article Outline

In this subsection, we pose the main questions and provide an outline of the paper.

1.2.1. Main Questions

In this paper on bank liquidity, we answer the following questions.

Question 1 (banking model). Can we model banksโ€™ liquid assets and nett cash outflows as well as LCRs in a stochastic framework? (compare with Section 2).

Question 2 (bank liquidity in a numerical quantitative framework). Can we explain and provide numerical examples of bank liquidity dynamics? (refer to Section 3).

Question 3 (bank liquidity in a theoretical quantitative framework). Can we devise a liquidity provisioning strategy in a theoretical quantitative framework? (compare with Section 4).

1.2.2. Paper Outline

The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 1 introduces the concept of liquidity risk while providing an appropriate literature review. A stochastic LCR model for bank liquidity is constructed in Section 2. Issues pertaining to bank liquidity in a numerical quantitative framework are discussed in Section 3. Section 4 treats liquidity in a theoretical quantitative manner. Finally, we provide concluding remarks in Section 5.

2. Bank Liquidity Model

In the sequel, we use the notational convention โ€œsubscript ๐‘ก or ๐‘ โ€ to represent (possibly) random processes, while โ€œbracket ๐‘ก or ๐‘ โ€ is used to denote deterministic processes. The assessment of a bankโ€™s relative composition of the stock of high-quality liquid assets (liquid assets) and nett cash outflows, is one of the primary ways of analyzing its liquidity position. In this regard, we consider a measure of liquidity offered by the LCR. Before the GFC, banks were prosperous with high LCRs, high cash inflows, low interest rates, and low nett cash outflows. This was followed by the collapse of liquidity, exploding default rates, and the effects thereof. We make the following assumption to set the space and time index that we consider in our LCR model.

Assumption 2.1 (filtered probability space and time index). Throughout, we assume that we are working with a filtered probability spaceโ€‰โ€‰(ฮฉ,โ„ฑ,โ„™)โ€‰โ€‰with filtrationโ€‰โ€‰{โ„ฑ๐‘ก}๐‘กโ‰ฅ0โ€‰โ€‰on a time index setโ€‰โ€‰[0,๐‘‡]. โ€‰We assume that the aforementioned space satisfies the usual conditions. Underโ€‰โ€‰โ„™,โ€‰โ€‰{๐‘Š๐‘ก;0โ‰ค๐‘กโ‰ค๐‘‡,๐‘Š0=0}โ€‰โ€‰is anโ€‰โ€‰โ„ฑ๐‘ก-Brownian motion.

Furthermore, we are able to produce a system of stochastic differential equations that provide information about the stock of high-quality liquid assets (liquid assets) at time ๐‘ก with ๐‘ฅ1โˆถฮฉร—[0,๐‘‡]โ†’โ„+ denoted by ๐‘ฅ1๐‘ก and nett cash outflows at time ๐‘ก with ๐‘ฅ2โˆถฮฉร—[0,๐‘‡]โ†’โ„+ denoted by ๐‘ฅ2๐‘ก and their relationship. The dynamics of liquid assets, ๐‘ฅ1๐‘ก, is stochastic in nature because it depends in part on the stochastic rates of return on assets and cash inflow and outflow (see [9] for more details) and the securitization market. Also, the dynamics of the nett cash outflow, ๐‘ฅ2๐‘ก, is stochastic because its value has a reliance on cash inflows as well as liquidity and market risk that have randomness associated with them. Furthermore, for ๐‘ฅโˆถฮฉร—[0,๐‘‡]โ†’โ„2 we use the notation ๐‘ฅ๐‘ก to denote ๐‘ฅ๐‘ก=โŽกโŽขโŽขโŽฃ๐‘ฅ1๐‘ก๐‘ฅ2๐‘กโŽคโŽฅโŽฅโŽฆ,(2.1) and represent the LCR with ๐‘™โˆถฮฉร—[0,๐‘‡]โ†’โ„+ by ๐‘™๐‘ก=๐‘ฅ1๐‘ก๐‘ฅ2๐‘ก.(2.2) It is important for banks that ๐‘™๐‘ก in (2.2) has to be sufficiently high to ensure high bank liquidity.

2.1. Liquid Assets

In this section, we discuss the stock of high-quality liquid assets constituted by cash, CB reserves, marketable securities, and government/CB bank debt issued.

2.1.1. Description of Liquid Assets

The first component of stock of high-quality liquid assets is cash that is made up of banknotes and coins. According to [1], a CB reserve should be able to be drawn down in times of stress. In this regard, local supervisors should discuss and agree with the relevant CB the extent to which CB reserves should count toward the stock of liquid assets.

Marketable securities represent claims on or claims guaranteed by sovereigns, CBs, noncentral government public sector entities (PSEs), the Bank for International Settlements (BIS), the International Monetary Fund (IMF), the European Commission (EC), or multilateral development banks. This is conditional on all the following criteria being met. These claims are assigned a 0% risk weight under the Basel II standardized approach. Also, deep repo-markets should exist for these securities and that they are not issued by banks or other financial service entities.

Another category of stock of high-quality liquid assets refers to government/CB bank debt issued in domestic currencies by the country in which the liquidity risk is being taken by the bankโ€™s home country (see, e.g., [1, 4]).

2.1.2. Dynamics of Liquid Assets

In this section, we consider ๐‘‘โ„Ž๐‘ก=๐‘Ÿโ„Ž๐‘ก๐‘‘๐‘ก+๐œŽโ„Ž๐‘ก๐‘‘๐‘Šโ„Ž๐‘ก๎€ท๐‘ก,โ„Ž0๎€ธ=โ„Ž0,(2.3) where the stochastic processes โ„Žโˆถฮฉร—[0,๐‘‡]โ†’โ„+ are the return per unit of liquid assets, ๐‘Ÿโ„Žโ†’โ„+ is the rate of return per liquid asset unit, the scalar ๐œŽโ„Žโˆถ๐‘‡โ†’โ„ is the volatility in the rate of returns, and ๐‘Šโ„Žโˆถฮฉร—[0,๐‘‡]โ†’โ„ is standard Brownian motion. Before the GFC, risky asset returns were much higher than those of riskless assets, making the former a more attractive but much riskier investment. It is inefficient for banks to invest all in risky or riskless securities with asset allocation being important. In this regard, it is necessary to make the following assumption to distinguish between risky (e.g., marketable securities and government/CB bank debt) and riskless assets (cash) for future computations.

Assumption 2.2 (liquid assets). Suppose from the outset that liquid assets are held in the financial market withโ€‰โ€‰๐‘›+1โ€‰โ€‰asset classes. One of these assets is riskless (cash) while the assetsโ€‰โ€‰1,2,โ€ฆ,๐‘›โ€‰โ€‰are risky.

The risky liquid assets evolve continuously in time and are modelled using an ๐‘›-dimensional Brownian motion. In this multidimensional context, the asset returns in the ๐‘˜th liquid asset class per unit of the ๐‘˜th class is denoted by ๐‘ฆ๐‘˜๐‘ก,๐‘˜โˆˆโ„•๐‘›={0,1,2,โ€ฆ,๐‘›} where ๐‘ฆโˆถฮฉร—[0,๐‘‡]โ†’โ„๐‘›+1. Thus, the return per liquid asset unit is ๎€ท๐‘ฆ=๐ถ(๐‘ก),๐‘ฆ1๐‘ก,โ€ฆ,๐‘ฆ๐‘›๐‘ก๎€ธ,(2.4) where ๐ถ(๐‘ก) represents the return on cash and ๐‘ฆ1๐‘ก,โ€ฆ,๐‘ฆ๐‘›๐‘ก represents the risky return. Furthermore, we can model ๐‘ฆ as ๐‘‘๐‘ฆ๐‘ก=๐‘Ÿ๐‘ฆ๐‘ก๐‘‘๐‘ก+ฮฃ๐‘ฆ๐‘ก๐‘‘๐‘Š๐‘ฆ๐‘ก๎€ท๐‘ก,๐‘ฆ0๎€ธ=๐‘ฆ0,(2.5) where ๐‘Ÿ๐‘ฆโˆถ๐‘‡โ†’โ„๐‘›+1 denotes the rate of liquid asset returns, ฮฃ๐‘ฆ๐‘กโˆˆโ„(๐‘›+1)ร—๐‘› is a matrix of liquid asset returns, and ๐‘Š๐‘ฆโˆถฮฉร—[0,๐‘‡]โ†’โ„๐‘› is standard Brownian motion. Notice that there are only ๐‘› scalar Brownian motions due to one of the liquid assets being riskless.

We assume that the investment strategy ๐œ‹โˆถ๐‘‡โ†’โ„๐‘›+1 is outside the simplex ๎‚†๐‘†=๐œ‹โˆˆ๐š๐‘›+1๎€ท๐œ‹โˆถ๐œ‹=0,โ€ฆ,๐œ‹๐‘›๎€ธ๐‘‡,๐œ‹0+โ‹ฏ+๐œ‹๐‘›=1,๐œ‹0โ‰ฅ0,โ€ฆ๐œ‹๐‘›๎‚‡โ‰ฅ0.(2.6) In this case, short selling is possible. The liquid asset return is then โ„Žโˆถฮฉร—๐‘…โ†’โ„+, where the dynamics of โ„Ž can be written as ๐‘‘โ„Ž๐‘ก=๐œ‹๐‘‡๐‘ก๐‘‘๐‘ฆ๐‘ก=๐œ‹๐‘‡๐‘ก๐‘Ÿ๐‘ฆ๐‘ก๐‘‘๐‘ก+๐œ‹๐‘‡๐‘กฮฃ๐‘ฆ๐‘ก๐‘‘๐‘Š๐‘ฆ๐‘ก.(2.7) This notation can be simplified as follows. We denote ๐‘Ÿ๐ถ(๐‘ก)=๐‘Ÿ๐‘ฆ0(๐‘ก),๐‘Ÿ๐ถโˆถ๐‘‡โŸถโ„+๐‘Ÿ,therateofreturnoncash,๐‘ฆ๐‘ก=๎‚ต๐‘Ÿ๐ถ๎‚๐‘Ÿ(๐‘ก),๐‘ฆ๐‘ก๐‘‡+๐‘Ÿ๐ถ(๐‘ก)1๐‘›๎‚ถ๐‘‡,ฬƒ๐‘Ÿ๐‘ฆโˆถ๐‘‡โŸถโ„๐‘›,๐œ‹๐‘ก=๎‚€๐œ‹0๐‘ก,๎‚๐œ‹๐‘‡๐‘ก๎‚๐‘‡=๎€ท๐œ‹0๐‘ก,๐œ‹1๐‘ก,โ€ฆ,๐œ‹๐‘˜๐‘ก๎€ธ๐‘‡,๎‚๐œ‹โˆถ๐‘‡โŸถโ„๐‘˜,ฮฃ๐‘ฆ๐‘ก=โŽ›โŽœโŽœโŽ๎‚ฮฃ0โ‹ฏ0๐‘ฆ๐‘กโŽžโŽŸโŽŸโŽ ,๎‚ฮฃ๐‘ฆ๐‘กโˆˆโ„๐‘›ร—๐‘›,๎‚๐ถ๐‘ก=๎‚ฮฃ๐‘ฆ๐‘ก๎‚‹ฮฃ๐‘ฆ๐‘ก๐‘‡๐œ‹.Then,wehavethat๐‘‡๐‘ก๐‘Ÿ๐‘ฆ๐‘ก=๐œ‹0๐‘ก๐‘Ÿ๐ถ(๐‘ก)+๎‚๐œ‹๐‘ก๐‘—๐‘‡ฬƒ๐‘Ÿ๐‘ฆ๐‘ก+๎‚๐œ‹๐‘ก๐‘—๐‘‡๐‘Ÿ๐ถ(๐‘ก)1๐‘›=๐‘Ÿ๐ถ(๐‘ก)+๎‚๐œ‹๐‘‡๐‘กฬƒ๐‘Ÿ๐‘ฆ๐‘ก,๐œ‹๐‘‡๐‘กฮฃ๐‘ฆ๐‘ก๐‘‘๐‘Š๐‘ฆ๐‘ก=๎‚๐œ‹๐‘‡๐‘ก๎‚ฮฃ๐‘ฆ๐‘ก๐‘‘๐‘Š๐‘ฆ๐‘ก,๐‘‘โ„Ž๐‘ก=๎‚ƒ๐‘Ÿ๐ถ(๐‘ก)+๎‚๐œ‹๐‘‡๐‘กฬƒ๐‘Ÿ๐‘ฆ๐‘ก๎‚„๐‘‘๐‘ก+๎‚๐œ‹๐‘‡๐‘ก๎‚ฮฃ๐‘ฆ๐‘ก๐‘‘๐‘Š๐‘ฆ๐‘ก๎€ท๐‘ก,โ„Ž0๎€ธ=โ„Ž0.(2.8)

2.2. Nett Cash Outflows

In this section, we discuss nett cash outflows arising from cash outflows and inflows.

2.2.1. Description of Nett Cash Outflows

Cash outflows are constituted by retail deposits, unsecured wholesale funding secured funding and additional liabilities (see, e.g., [1]). The latter category includes requirements about liabilities involving derivative collateral calls related to a downgrade of up to 3 notches, market valuation changes on derivatives transactions, valuation changes on posted noncash or non-high-quality sovereign debt collateral securing derivative transactions, asset backed commercial paper (ABCP), special investment vehicles (SIVs), conduits, special purpose vehicles (SPVs), and the currently undrawn portion of committed credit and liquidity facilities.

Cash inflows are made up of amounts receivable from retail counterparties, amounts receivable from wholesale counterparties, receivables in respect of repo and reverse repo transactions backed by illiquid assets, and securities lending/borrowing transactions where illiquid assets are borrowed as well as other cash inflows.

According to [1], nett cash inflows is defined as cumulative expected cash outflows minus cumulative expected cash inflows arising in the specified stress scenario in the time period under consideration. This is the nett cumulative liquidity mismatch position under the stress scenario measured at the test horizon. Cumulative expected cash outflows are calculated by multiplying outstanding balances of various categories or types of liabilities by assumed percentages that are expected to roll off and by multiplying specified draw-down amounts to various off-balance sheet commitments. Cumulative expected cash inflows are calculated by multiplying amounts receivable by a percentage that reflects expected inflow under the stress scenario.

2.2.2. Dynamics of Nett Cash Outflows

Essentially, mortgagors are free to vary their cash inflow rates. Roughly speaking, this rate should be reduced for high LCRs and increased beyond the normal rate when LCRs are too low. In the sequel, the stochastic process ๐‘ข1โˆถฮฉร—[0,๐‘‡]โ†’โ„+ is the normal cash inflow rate per nett cash inflow unit whose value at time ๐‘ก is denoted by ๐‘ข1๐‘ก. In this case, ๐‘ข1๐‘ก๐‘‘๐‘ก turns out to be the cash inflow rate per unit of the nett cash inflow over the time period (๐‘ก,๐‘ก+๐‘‘๐‘ก). A notion related to this is the adjustment to the cash inflow rate per unit of the nett cash inflow rate for a higher or lower LCR, ๐‘ข2โˆถฮฉร—[0,๐‘‡]โ†’โ„+, that will in closed loop be made dependent on the LCR. We denote the sum of ๐‘ข1 and ๐‘ข2 by the cash inflow rate ๐‘ข3โˆถฮฉร—[0,๐‘‡]โ†’โ„+, that is, ๐‘ข3๐‘ก=๐‘ข1๐‘ก+๐‘ข2๐‘ก,โˆ€๐‘ก.(2.9) Before the GFC, the cash inflow rate increased significantly as a consequence of rising liquidity. The following assumption is made in order to model the LCR in a stochastic framework.

Assumption 2.3 (cash inflow rate). The cash inflow,โ€‰๐‘ข3, is predictable with respect to {โ„ฑ๐‘ก}๐‘กโ‰ฅ0.
The cash inflow provides us with a means of controlling LCR dynamics. The dynamics of the cash outflow per unit of the nett cash outflow, ๐‘’โˆถฮฉร—[0,๐‘‡]โ†’โ„, is given by ๐‘‘๐‘’๐‘ก=๐‘Ÿ๐‘’๐‘ก๐‘‘๐‘ก+๐œŽ๐‘’๐‘ก๐‘‘๐‘Š๐‘’๐‘ก๎€ท๐‘ก,๐‘’0๎€ธ=๐‘’0,(2.10) where ๐‘’๐‘ก is the cash outflow per unit of the nett cash outflow, ๐‘Ÿ๐‘’โˆถ๐‘‡โ†’โ„ is the rate of outflow per unit of the nett cash outflow, the scalar ๐œŽ๐‘’โˆถ๐‘‡โ†’โ„ is the volatility in the outflow per nett cash outflow unit, and ๐‘Š๐‘’โˆถฮฉร—[0,๐‘‡]โ†’โ„ is standard Brownian motion.
Next, we take ๐‘–โˆถฮฉร—[0,๐‘‡]โ†’โ„+ as the nett cash outflow increase before cash outflow per monetary unit of the nett cash outflow, ๐‘Ÿ๐‘–โˆถ๐‘‡โ†’โ„+ is the rate of increase of nett cash outflows before cash outflow per nett cash outflow unit, the scalar ๐œŽ๐‘–โˆˆโ„ is the volatility in the increase of nett cash outflows before outflow, and ๐‘Š๐‘–โˆถฮฉร—[0,๐‘‡]โ†’โ„ represents standard Brownian motion. Then, we set ๐‘‘๐‘–๐‘ก=๐‘Ÿ๐‘–๐‘ก๐‘‘๐‘ก+๐œŽ๐‘–๐‘‘๐‘Š๐‘–๐‘ก๎€ท๐‘ก,๐‘–0๎€ธ=๐‘–0.(2.11) The stochastic process ๐‘–๐‘ก in (2.11) may typically originate from nett cash flow volatility that may result from changes in market activity, cash supply, and inflation.

2.3. The Liquidity Coverage Ratio

This section discusses ratio analysis and liquidity coverage ratio dynamics.

2.3.1. Ratio Analysis

Ratio analysis is conducted on the bankโ€™s balance sheet composition. In this case, the LCR measures a bankโ€™s ability to access funding for a 30-day period of acute market stress. In this paper, as in Basel III, we are interested in the LCR that is defined as the sum of interbank assets and securities issued by public entities as a percentage of interbank liabilities. The LCR formula is given by LiquidityCoverageRatio=StockofHighQualityLiquidAssets.NettCashOut๏ฌ‚owsovera30-dayPeriod(2.12) This ratio measures the bank systemโ€™s liquidity position that allows the assessment of a bankโ€™s capacity to ensure the coverage of some of its more immediate liabilities with highly available assets. It also identifies the amount of unencumbered, high-quality liquid assets a bank holds that can be used to offset the nett cash outflows it would encounter under a short-term stress scenario specified by supervisors, including both specific and systemic shocks.

2.3.2. Liquidity Coverage Ratio Dynamics

Using the equations for liquid assets ๐‘ฅ1 and nett cash outflow ๐‘ฅ2, we have that ๐‘‘๐‘ฅ1๐‘ก=๐‘ฅ1๐‘ก๐‘‘โ„Ž๐‘ก+๐‘ฅ2๐‘ก๐‘ข3๐‘ก๐‘‘๐‘กโˆ’๐‘ฅ2๐‘ก๐‘‘๐‘’๐‘ก=๎‚ƒ๐‘Ÿ๐ถ(๐‘ก)๐‘ฅ1๐‘ก+๐‘ฅ1๐‘ก๎‚๐œ‹๐‘‡๐‘กฬƒ๐‘Ÿ๐‘ฆ๐‘ก+๐‘ฅ2๐‘ก๐‘ข1๐‘ก+๐‘ฅ2๐‘ก๐‘ข2๐‘กโˆ’๐‘ฅ2๐‘ก๐‘Ÿ๐‘’๐‘ก๎‚„+๎‚ƒ๐‘ฅ๐‘‘๐‘ก1๐‘ก๎‚๐œ‹๐‘‡๐‘ก๎‚ฮฃ๐‘ฆ๐‘ก๐‘‘๐‘Š๐‘ฆ๐‘กโˆ’๐‘ฅ2๐‘ก๐œŽ๐‘’๐‘‘๐‘Š๐‘’๐‘ก๎‚„,๐‘‘๐‘ฅ2๐‘ก=๐‘ฅ2๐‘ก๐‘‘๐‘–๐‘กโˆ’๐‘ฅ2๐‘ก๐‘‘๐‘’๐‘ก=๐‘ฅ2๐‘ก๎€บ๐‘Ÿ๐‘–๐‘ก๐‘‘๐‘ก+๐œŽ๐‘–๐‘‘๐‘Š๐‘–๐‘ก๎€ปโˆ’๐‘ฅ2๐‘ก๎€บ๐‘Ÿ๐‘’๐‘ก๐‘‘๐‘ก+๐œŽ๐‘’๐‘‘๐‘Š๐‘’๐‘ก๎€ป=๐‘ฅ2๐‘ก๎€บ๐‘Ÿ๐‘–๐‘กโˆ’๐‘Ÿ๐‘’๐‘ก๎€ป๐‘‘๐‘ก+๐‘ฅ2๐‘ก๎€บ๐œŽ๐‘–๐‘‘๐‘Š๐‘–๐‘กโˆ’๐œŽ๐‘’๐‘‘๐‘Š๐‘’๐‘ก๎€ป.(2.13) The SDEs (2.13) may be rewritten into matrix-vector form in the following way.

Definition 2.4 (stochastic system for the LCR model). Define the stochastic systemfor the LCR model as ๐‘‘๐‘ฅ๐‘ก=๐ด๐‘ก๐‘ฅ๐‘ก๎€ท๐‘ฅ๐‘‘๐‘ก+๐‘๐‘ก๎€ธ๐‘ข๐‘ก๐‘‘๐‘ก+๐‘Ž๐‘ก๎€ท๐‘ฅ๐‘‘๐‘ก+๐‘†๐‘ก,๐‘ข๐‘ก๎€ธ๐‘‘๐‘Š๐‘ก,(2.14) with the various terms in this stochastic differential equation being ๐‘ข๐‘ก=โŽกโŽขโŽขโŽฃ๐‘ข2๐‘ก๎‚๐œ‹๐‘กโŽคโŽฅโŽฅโŽฆ[],๐‘ขโˆถฮฉร—0,๐‘‡โŸถโ„๐‘›+1,๐ด๐‘ก=โŽกโŽขโŽขโŽฃ๐‘Ÿ๐ถ(๐‘ก)โˆ’๐‘Ÿ๐‘’๐‘ก0๐‘Ÿ๐‘–๐‘กโˆ’๐‘Ÿ๐‘’๐‘กโŽคโŽฅโŽฅโŽฆ,๐‘๎€ท๐‘ฅ๐‘ก๎€ธ=โŽกโŽขโŽขโŽฃ๐‘ฅ2๐‘ก๐‘ฅ1๐‘ก๎‚๐‘Ÿ๐‘ฆ๐‘ก๐‘‡โŽคโŽฅโŽฅโŽฆ00,๐‘Ž๐‘ก=โŽกโŽขโŽขโŽฃ๐‘ฅ2๐‘ก๐‘ข1๐‘ก0โŽคโŽฅโŽฅโŽฆ,๐‘†๎€ท๐‘ฅ๐‘ก,๐‘ข๐‘ก๎€ธ=โŽกโŽขโŽขโŽฃ๐‘ฅ1๐‘ก๎‚๐œ‹๐‘‡๐‘ก๎‚ฮฃ๐‘ฆ๐‘กโˆ’๐‘ฅ2๐‘ก๐œŽ๐‘’00โˆ’๐‘ฅ2๐‘ก๐œŽ๐‘’๐‘ฅ2๐‘ก๐œŽ๐‘–โŽคโŽฅโŽฅโŽฆ,๐‘Š๐‘ก=โŽกโŽขโŽขโŽขโŽขโŽฃ๐‘Š๐‘ฆ๐‘ก๐‘Š๐‘’๐‘ก๐‘Š๐‘–๐‘กโŽคโŽฅโŽฅโŽฅโŽฅโŽฆ,(2.15) where ๐‘Š๐‘ฆ๐‘ก,๐‘Š๐‘’๐‘ก, and ๐‘Š๐‘–๐‘ก are mutually (stochastically) independent standard Brownian motions. It is assumed that for all ๐‘กโˆˆ๐‘‡, ๐œŽ๐‘’๐‘ก>0, ๐œŽ๐‘–๐‘ก>0 and ๎‚๐ถ๐‘ก>0. Often the time argument of the functions ๐œŽ๐‘’ and ๐œŽ๐‘– is omitted.

We can rewrite (2.14) as follows: ๐‘๎€ท๐‘ฅ๐‘ก๎€ธ๐‘ข๐‘กโŽกโŽขโŽขโŽฃ๐‘ฅโˆถ=2๐‘ก0โŽคโŽฅโŽฅโŽฆ๐‘ข2๐‘ก+โŽกโŽขโŽขโŽฃ๐‘ฅ1๐‘ก๎‚๐‘Ÿ๐‘ฆ๐‘ก๐‘‡0โŽคโŽฅโŽฅโŽฆ๎‚๐œ‹๐‘กโŽกโŽขโŽขโŽฃโŽคโŽฅโŽฅโŽฆ๐‘ฅโˆถ=0100๐‘ก๐‘ข3๐‘ก+๐‘›๎“๐‘š=1โŽกโŽขโŽขโŽฃ๐‘ฅ1๐‘กฬƒ๐‘Ÿ๐‘ก๐‘ฆ,๐‘š0โŽคโŽฅโŽฅโŽฆ๎‚๐œ‹๐‘š๐‘กโˆถ=๐ต0๐‘ฅ๐‘ก๐‘ข0๐‘ก+๐‘›๎“๐‘š=1โŽกโŽขโŽขโŽฃฬƒ๐‘Ÿ๐‘ก๐‘ฆ,๐‘š0โŽคโŽฅโŽฅโŽฆ๐‘ฅ00๐‘ก๎‚๐œ‹๐‘š๐‘กโˆถ=๐‘›๎“๐‘š=0๎€บ๐ต๐‘š๐‘ฅ๐‘ก๎€ป๐‘ข๐‘š๐‘ก,๐‘†๎€ท๐‘ฅ๐‘ก,๐‘ข๐‘ก๎€ธ๐‘‘๐‘Š๐‘ก=โŽกโŽขโŽขโŽฃ๎‚ƒ๎‚๐œ‹๐‘‡๐‘ก๎‚๐ถ๐‘ก๎‚๐œ‹๐‘ก๎‚„1/20โŽคโŽฅโŽฅโŽฆ๐‘ฅ00๐‘ก๐‘‘๐‘Š1๐‘ก+โŽกโŽขโŽขโŽฃ0โˆ’๐œŽ๐‘’0โˆ’๐œŽ๐‘’โŽคโŽฅโŽฅโŽฆ๐‘ฅ๐‘ก๐‘‘๐‘Š2๐‘ก+โŽกโŽขโŽขโŽฃ000๐œŽ๐‘–โŽคโŽฅโŽฅโŽฆ๐‘ฅ๐‘ก๐‘‘๐‘Š3๐‘ก=3๎“๐‘—=1๎€บ๐‘€๐‘—๐‘—๎€ท๐‘ข๐‘ก๎€ธ๐‘ฅ๐‘ก๎€ป๐‘‘๐‘Š๐‘ก๐‘—๐‘—,(2.16) where ๐ต and ๐‘€ are only used for notational purposes to simplify the equations. From the stochastic system given by (2.14) it is clear that ๐‘ข=(๐‘ข2,๎‚๐œ‹) affects only the stochastic differential equation of ๐‘ฅ1๐‘ก but not that of ๐‘ฅ2๐‘ก. In particular, for (2.14) we have that ๎‚๐œ‹ affects the variance of ๐‘ฅ1๐‘ก and the drift of ๐‘ฅ1๐‘ก via the term ๐‘ฅ1๐‘ก๎‚๐‘Ÿ๐‘ฆ๐‘ก๐‘‡๎‚๐œ‹๐‘ก. On the other hand, ๐‘ข2 affects only the drift of ๐‘ฅ1๐‘ก. Then (2.14) becomes ๐‘‘๐‘ฅ๐‘ก=๐ด๐‘ก๐‘ฅ๐‘ก๐‘‘๐‘ก+๐‘›๎“๐‘—=0๎€บ๐ต๐‘—๐‘ฅ๐‘ก๎€ป๐‘ข๐‘—๐‘ก๐‘‘๐‘ก+๐‘Ž๐‘ก๐‘‘๐‘ก+3๎“๐‘—=1๎€บ๐‘€๐‘—๎€ท๐‘ข๐‘ก๎€ธ๐‘ฅ๐‘ก๎€ป๐‘‘๐‘Š๐‘ก๐‘—๐‘—.(2.17) The model can be simplified if attention is restricted to the system with the LCR, as stated earlier, denoted in this section by ๐‘ฅ๐‘ก=๐‘ฅ1๐‘ก/๐‘ฅ2๐‘ก.

Definition 2.5 (stochastic model for a simplified LCR). Define the simplified LCR system by the SDE ๐‘‘๐‘ฅ๐‘ก=๐‘ฅ๐‘ก๎‚ธ๐‘Ÿ๐ถ(๐‘ก)+๐‘Ÿ๐‘’๐‘กโˆ’๐‘Ÿ๐‘–๐‘ก+(๐œŽ๐‘’)2+๎€ท๐œŽ๐‘–๎€ธ2+๎‚๐‘Ÿ๐‘ฆ๐‘ก๐‘‡๎‚๐œ‹๐‘ก๎‚น+๎€บ๐‘ข๐‘‘๐‘ก1๐‘ก+๐‘ข2๐‘กโˆ’๐‘Ÿ๐‘’๐‘กโˆ’(๐œŽ๐‘’)2๎€ป+๎‚ƒ๐‘‘๐‘ก(๐œŽ๐‘’)2๎€ท1โˆ’๐‘ฅ๐‘ก๎€ธ2+๎€ท๐œŽ๐‘–๎€ธ2๐‘ฅ2๐‘ก+๐‘ฅ2๐‘ก๎‚๐œ‹๐‘‡๐‘ก๎‚๐ถ๐‘ก๎‚๐œ‹๐‘ก๎‚„1/2๐‘‘๐‘Š๐‘ก๎€ท๐‘ก,๐‘ฅ0๎€ธ=๐‘ฅ0.(2.18) Note that in the drift of the SDE (2.18), the term โˆ’๐‘Ÿ๐‘’๐‘ก+๐‘ฅ๐‘ก๐‘Ÿ๐‘’๐‘ก=โˆ’๐‘Ÿ๐‘’๐‘ก๎€ท๐‘ฅ๐‘ก๎€ธโˆ’1,(2.19) appears because it models the effect of the decline of both liquid assets and nett cash outflows. Similarly the term โˆ’(๐œŽ๐‘’)2+๐‘ฅ๐‘ก(๐œŽ๐‘’)2=(๐œŽ๐‘’)2(๐‘ฅ๐‘กโˆ’1) appears.

3. Bank Liquidity in a Numerical Quantitative Framework

In this section, we discuss bank liquidity in a numerical quantitative framework. Recently the finance literature has devoted more attention to modeling and assessing liquidity risk in a numerical quantitative framework (see, e.g., [5, 8, 9]).

3.1. Bank Liquidity: Numerical Exampleโ€‰โ€‰1

In this subsection, we use the data supplied in [6] (see, also, Appendices A.1 and A.2) to assess the liquidity of banks. The dataset originates from a supervisory liquidity report for Dutch banks. It covers a detailed breakdown of liquid assets and liabilities including cash in- and outflows of banks (see, also, [5]).

3.1.1. Data Description: Numerical Exampleโ€‰โ€‰1

The aforementioned supervisory liquidity report includes on- and off-balance sheet items for about 85 Dutch banks (foreign bank subsidiaries included) with a breakdown per item (average granularity of about 7 items per bank). The report presents month end data available for the period October 2003 to March 2009. In this case, supervisory requirements dictate that actual bank liquidity must exceed required liquidity, at both a one-week and a one-month horizon. Actual liquidity is defined as the stock of liquid assets (weighted for haircuts) and recognized cash inflows (weighted for their liquidity value) during the test period. Required liquidity is defined as the assumed calls on contingent liquidity lines, assumed withdrawals of deposits, drying up of wholesale funding, and liabilities due to derivatives. In this way, the liquidity report comprises a combined stock and cash flow approach, in which respect it is a forward looking concept. The weights, ๐‘ค๐‘–, of the assumed haircuts on liquid assets and run-off rates of liabilities are presented in last two columns of Tables 1 and 2 below. In this regard, the pecking order hypothesis is tested empirically in [5] by classifying the assets and liabilities of the banks in our sample according to the month weights in the liquidity report (as presented in the last column of Tables 1 and 2). In the report, the ๐‘ค๐‘– values are fixed (see, e.g., [6]) and reflect the bank-specific and market-wide situation. The ๐‘ค๐‘– values are based on best practices of values of haircuts on liquid assets and run-off rates of liabilities of the banking industry and credit rating agencies.

The various balance sheet and cash flow items in the prudential report [6] are assumed to reflect the instruments which banks use in liquidity risk management by way of responding to shocks. The instruments are expressed in gross amounts. To enhance the economic interpretation we define coherent groups of instruments and the sum of item amounts per group. The first column of Tables 1 and 2 below provides the group classification. Here, the second columns in these tables describe the particular class of assets and liabilities. For the liquidity test for the full month, a distinction is made between non-scheduled items and scheduled items. By contrast to non-scheduled items, scheduled items are included on the basis of their possible or probable due dates. For the liquidity test for the first week, scheduled items are only included if they are explicitly taken into account in day-to-day liquidity management Treasury operations. In Tables 1 and 2 below, scheduled items are indicated by the letter S.

3.1.2. Data Presentation: Numerical Exampleโ€‰โ€‰1

In this section, we firstly represent data related to assets and then data related to liabilities.

3.1.3. Data Analysis: Numerical Exampleโ€‰โ€‰1

From Tables 1 and 2, we have seen that the behavior of banks can be described by rather simple indicators constructed from firm-specific balance sheet data. Although they are descriptive in nature, the measures identify trends in banks behavior that convey forward looking information on market-wide developments. A key insight from the analysis is that while banks usually follow a pecking order in their balance sheet adjustments (by making larger adjustments to the most liquid balance sheet items compared to less liquid items), during the crisis banks were more inclined to a static response. This suggests that they have less room to follow a pecking order in their liquidity risk management in stressed circumstances. It implies that banks responses in crises may have more material effects on the economy, since a static response rule means that banks are more likely to adjust their (less liquid) retail lending and deposits than under normal market conditions. A sufficient stock of liquid buffers could prevent that banks are forced to such detrimental static responses, which lends support to the initiatives of the Basel Committee to tighten liquidity regulation for banks (see, e.g., [1]).

The measures for size and the number of extreme balance sheet adjustments gauge the time dimension of macroprudential risk, and indicators of the dependency and concentration of reactions capture the cross-sectoral dimension. The measures are robust to different specifications and distributions of the data. Applied to Dutch banks, the measures show that the number, size, and similarity of responses substantially changed during the crisis, in particular on certain market segments. They also indicate that the nature of banks behavior is asymmetric, being more intense in busts than in booms. Furthermore, during the crisis the deleveraging of large banks started earlier was more intense and more advanced than the deleveraging of smaller banks.

Given these findings, the indicators are useful for macroprudential analysis, for instance with regard to monitoring frameworks. Our analysis underscores the relevance of using several indicators of liquidity risk at the same time, given the different leads and lags of the measures with systemic risk. The empirical results also provide useful information for financial stability models. A better understanding of banks behavior helps to improve the microfoundations of such models, especially with regard to the behavioral assumptions of heterogeneous institutions. Finally, the empirical findings in our study are relevant to understand the role of banks in monetary transmission and to assess the potential demand for CB finance in stress situations. The measures explain developments of financial intermediation channels (wholesale and retail, unsecured, secured, etc.) along the cross-sectional and time dimensions. They also shed more light on the size and number of banks that rely on CB financing.

3.2. Bank Liquidity: Numerical Exampleโ€‰โ€‰2

In this section, we provide a simulation of the LCR dynamics given in (2.18).

3.2.1. Simulation: Numerical Exampleโ€‰โ€‰2

In this subsection, we provide parameters and values for a numerical simulation. The parameters and their corresponding values for the simulation are shown in Table 3.

3.2.2. LCR Dynamics: Numerical Exampleโ€‰โ€‰2

In Figure 1, we provide the LCR dynamics in the form of a trajectory derived from (2.18).

3.2.3. Properties of the LCR Trajectory: Numerical Exampleโ€‰โ€‰2

Figure 1 shows the simulated trajectory for the LCR of low liquidity assets. Here different values of banking parameters are collected in Table 3. The number of jumps of the trajectory was limited to 1001, with the initial values for ๐‘™ fixed at 20.

As we know, banks manage their liquidity by offsetting liabilities via assets. It is actually the diversification of the bankโ€™s assets and liabilities that expose them to liquidity shocks. Here, we use ratio analysis (in the form of the LCR) to manage liquidity risk relating various components in the bankโ€™s balance sheets. In Figure 1, we observe that between ๐‘ก=2000 and ๐‘ก=2005, there was a significant decrease in the trajectory which shows that either liquid assets declined or nett cash outflows increased.

There was also an increase between ๐‘ก=2005 and ๐‘ก=2007 which suggests that either liquid assets increased or nett cash outflows decreased. There was an even sharper increase subsequent to ๐‘ก=2007 which comes as somewhat of a surprise. In order to mitigate the aforementioned increase in liquidity risk, banks can use several facilities such as repurchase agreements to secure more funding. However, a significant increase was recorded between ๐‘ก=2005 and ๐‘ก=2008, with the trend showing that banks have more liquid assets on their books. If ๐‘™>0, it demonstrated that the banks has kept a high volume of liquid assets which might be stemming from quality liquidity risk management. In order for banks to improve liquidity they may use debt securities that allow savings from nonfinancial private sectors, a good network of branches and other competitive strategies.

The LCR has some limitations regarding the characterization of the banks liquidity position. Therefore, other ratios could be used for a more complete analysis taking into account the structure of the short-term assets and liabilities of residual maturities.

4. Bank Liquidity in a Theoretical Quantitative Framework

In this section, we investigate bank liquidity in a theoretical quantitative framework. In particular, we characterize a liquidity provisioning strategy and discuss residual aggregate risk in order to eventually determine the appropriate value of the price process. In order to model uncertainty, in the sequel, we consider the filter probability space (ฮฉ,๐”ฝ,(โ„ฑ๐‘ก)0โ‰ค๐‘กโ‰ค๐‘‡,โ„™),๐‘‡โˆˆโ„ described in Assumption 2.1.

4.1. Preliminaries about the Liquidity Provisioning Strategy

Firstly, we consider a dynamic liquidity provisioning strategy for a risky underlying illiquid asset process, (ฮ›๐‘ก)0โ‰ค๐‘กโ‰ค๐‘‡. For purposes of relating the discussion below to the GFC, we choose ฮ› to be residential mortgage loans hereafter known simply as mortgages. Mortgages were very illiquid (nonmarketable) before and during the GFC. In this case, for liquidity provisioning purposes, the more liquid marketable securities, ๐‘†โ€”judging by their credit rating before and during the GFCโ€”are used as a substitute for mortgages. This was true during the period before and during the GFC, with mortgage-backed securities being traded more easily than the underlying mortgages. Furthermore, we assume that the bank mainly holds illiquid mortgages and marketable securities (compare with the assets presented in Tables 1 and 2) with cash for investment being injected by outside investors. The liquid marketable securities, ๐‘†, are not completely correlated with the illiquid mortgages, ฮ›, creating market incompleteness. Under the probability measure, โ„™, the price of the traded substitute securities and the illiquid underlying mortgages are given by ๐‘‘๐‘†๐‘ก=๐‘†๐‘ก๎€บ๐œ‡๐‘ ๐‘‘๐‘ก+๐œŽ๐‘ ๐‘‘๐‘Š๐‘†๐‘ก๎€ป,๐‘‘ฮ›๐‘ก=ฮ›๐‘ก๎€บ๐œ‡ฮ›๐‘‘๐‘ก+๐œŽฮ›๐‘‘๐‘Šฮ›๐‘ก๎€ป,(4.1) respectively, where ๐œ‡ and ๐œŽ are constants. We define the constant market price of risk for securities as ๐œ†๐‘ =๐œ‡๐‘ โˆ’๐‘Ÿ๐œŽ.(4.2) We note that if the market correlation |๐œŒ| between ๐‘Š๐‘† and ๐‘Šฮ› is equal to one, then the securities and mortgages are completely correlated and the market is complete.

Let ฮ˜ be a liquidity provisioning strategy for the bankโ€™s asset portfolio. The dynamics of its wealth process is given by ๐‘‘ฮ ๐‘ก=๐‘›๐‘†๐‘ก๐‘‘๐‘†๐‘ก+๎€ทฮ ๐‘กโˆ’๐‘›๐‘†๐‘ก๐‘†๐‘ก๎€ธ๐‘Ÿ๐‘‘๐‘ก+๐‘‘๐ถ๐‘ก,(4.3) where ๐‘‘๐ถ๐‘ก is an amount of cash infused into the portfolio, ๐‘›๐‘†๐‘ก is the number of shares of securities held in the portfolio at time ๐‘ก,โ€‰โ€‰ฮ ๐‘ก is the value of the wealth process, and ๐‘Ÿ is the riskless interest rate. The cumulative cost process ๐ถ(ฮ˜) associated with the strategy, ฮ˜, is ๐ถ๐‘ก(ฬ€ฮ ฮ˜)=๐‘ก(๎€œฮ˜)โˆ’๐‘ก0๐‘›๐‘†๐‘ข๐‘‘ฬ€๐‘†๐‘ข,0โ‰ค๐‘กโ‰ค๐‘‡.(4.4) The cost process is the total amount of cash that has been injected from date 0 to date ๐‘ก. We determine a provisioning strategy that generate a payoff (ฮ›๐‘‡โˆ’๐พ)+ at the maturity ๐‘‡. The quantity โˆซ๐‘‡๐‘กexp{โˆ’๐‘Ÿ(๐‘ โˆ’๐‘ก)}๐‘‘๐ถ๐‘  is the discounted cash amount that needs to be injected into the portfolio between dates ๐‘ก and ๐‘‡. Since โˆซ๐‘‡๐‘กexp{โˆ’๐‘Ÿ(๐‘ โˆ’๐‘ก)}๐‘‘๐ถ๐‘  is uncertain, the risk-averse agent will focus on minimizing the associated ex-ante aggregate liquidity risk ๐š๐‘ก(ฮ˜)=๐”ผโ„™๎ƒฌ๎‚ต๎€œ๐‘‡๐‘กexp{โˆ’๐‘Ÿ(๐‘ โˆ’๐‘ก)}๐‘‘๐ถ๐‘ข๎‚ถ2๎ƒญ,0โ‰ค๐‘กโ‰ค๐‘‡.(4.5) It is clear that this concept is related to the conditioned expected square value of future costs. The strategy ฮ˜, 0โ‰ค๐‘กโ‰ค๐‘‡ is mean self-financing if its corresponding cost process ๐ถ=(๐ถ๐‘ก)0โ‰ค๐‘ก=๐‘‡ is a martingale. Furthermore, the strategy ฮ˜ is self-financing if and only if ฬ€ฮ ๐‘ก(ฬ€ฮ ฮ˜)=0(๎€œฮ˜)+๐‘ก0๐‘›๐‘†๐‘ข๐‘‘ฬ€๐‘†๐‘ข,0โ‰ค๐‘กโ‰ค๐‘‡.(4.6) A strategy ๎ฮ˜ is called an admissible continuation of ฮ˜ if ๎ฮ˜ coincides with ฮ˜ at all times before ๐‘ก and ฮ ๐‘ก(ฮ˜)=๐ฟ, โ„™ a.s. Moreover, a provisioning strategy is called liquidity risk minimizing if for any ๐‘กโˆˆ[0,๐‘‡], ฮ˜ minimizes the remaining liquidity risk. In other words, for any admissible continuous ๎ฮ˜ of ฮ˜ at ๐‘ก we have ๐š๐‘ก(ฮ˜)โ‰ค๐š๐‘ก๎‚€๎ฮ˜๎‚.(4.7) Criterion given in (4.5) can be formally rewritten as โˆ€๐‘กmin(๐‘›๐‘†,ฮ )๐š๐‘ก,subjecttoฮ ๐‘ก=๎€ทฮ›๐‘‡๎€ธโˆ’๐พ+.(4.8) We define the expected squared error of the cost over the next period as ๐”ผโ„™๎‚ƒ๎€ทฮ”๐ถ๐‘ก๎€ธ2๎‚„=๐”ผ๐‘ก๎‚ƒ๎€ทฮ ๐‘ก+ฮ”๐‘กโˆ’ฮ ๐‘กโˆ’๐‘›๐‘†๐‘ก๎€ท๐‘†๐‘ก+ฮ”๐‘กโˆ’๐‘†๐‘ก๎€ธโˆ’๎€ทฮ ๐‘กโˆ’๐‘›๐‘†๐‘ก๐‘†๐‘ก๎€ธ๎€ธ(exp{๐‘Ÿ(๐‘ก+ฮ”๐‘ก)}โˆ’exp{๐‘Ÿ๐‘ก})2๎‚„.(4.9) In the next section, we minimize the above quantity at each date, with respect to (๐‘›๐‘†0,๐‘›๐‘†ฮ”,โ€ฆ,๐‘›๐‘†๐‘ก+ฮ”๐‘ก) and also discuss the notion of a liquidity provisioning strategy.

4.2. Characterization of the Liquidity Provisioning Strategy

During the GFC, liquidity provisioning strategies involved several interesting elements. Firstly, private provisioning of liquidity was provided via the financial system. Secondly, there was a strong connection between financial fragility and cash-in-the-market pricing. Also, contagion and asymmetric information played a major role in the GFC. Finally, much of the debate on liquidity provisioning has been concerned with the provisioning of liquidity to financial institutions and resulting spillovers to the real economy. The next result characterizes the liquidity provisioning strategy that we study.

Theorem 4.1 (characterization of the provisioning strategy). The locally liquidity risk minimizing strategy is described by the following.(1)The investment in mortgages is ฬ€๐‘›๐‘†๐‘ก=๐œŽฮ›ฮ›๐‘ก๐œŽ๐‘†๐‘†๐‘ก๐œŒ๐ถฮ›๎€ท๐‘ก,ฮ›๐‘ก๎€ธ=๐œŽฮ›ฮ›๐‘ก๐œŽ๐‘†๐‘†๐‘ก๐œ‡๐œŒexp๎€ฝ๎€ทฮ›โˆ’๐‘Ÿโˆ’๐œŒ๐œŽฮ›๐œ†๐‘†๎€ธ๎€พ๐™ฝ๎€ท๐‘‘(๐‘‡โˆ’๐‘ก)1๎€ธ,,๐‘ก(4.10) where ๐œ†๐‘  is the Sharpe ratio and ๐ถ(๐‘ก,ฮ›๐‘ก) is the minimal entropy price ๐ถ๎€ท๐‘ก,ฮ›๐‘ก๎€ธ=exp{โˆ’๐‘Ÿ(๐‘‡โˆ’๐‘ก)}๐”ผโ„š๎‚ƒ๎€ทฮ›๐‘‡๎€ธโˆ’๐พ+๎‚„๐œ‡=exp๎€ฝ๎€ทฮ›โˆ’๐‘Ÿโˆ’๐œŒ๐œŽฮ›๐œ†๐‘†๎€ธ๎€พฮ›(๐‘‡โˆ’๐‘ก)๐‘ก๐™ฝ๎€ท๐‘‘1๎€ธ๎€ท๐‘‘,๐‘กโˆ’๐พexp{โˆ’๐‘Ÿ(๐‘‡โˆ’๐‘ก)}๐™ฝ2๎€ธ,,๐‘ก(4.11) where โ„š is the minimal martingale measure defined as ๐‘‘โ„š|||๐‘‘โ„™๐‘ก๎‚†โˆ’1=exp2ฮ›๐‘†2(๐‘‡โˆ’๐‘ก)โˆ’๐œ†๐‘†๎€ท๐‘Š๐‘†๐‘‡โˆ’๐‘Š๐‘†๐‘ก๎€ธ๎‚‡,๐‘‘1,๐‘ก=1๐œŽฮ›โˆš๎‚ธฮ›๐‘‡โˆ’๐‘กln๐‘ก๐พ+๎‚ต๐œ‡ฮ›โˆ’๐œŒ๐œŽฮ›๐œ†๐‘†+๐œŽฮ›22๎‚ถ๎‚น(๐‘‡โˆ’๐‘ก),๐‘‘2,๐‘ก=๐‘‘1,๐‘กโˆ’๐œŽฮ›โˆš๐‘‡โˆ’๐‘ก.(4.12)(2) The cash investment is ๐ถ๎€ท๐‘ก,ฮ›๐‘ก๎€ธโˆ’ฬ€๐‘›๐‘†๐‘ก๐‘†๐‘ก.(4.13) If the Sharpe ratio, ๐œ†๐‘ , of the traded substitute securities is equal to zero, the minimal martingale measure coincides with the original measure โ„™, and the above strategy is globally liquidity risk minimizing.

Proof. Let ฬ€๐‘†๐‘กโ‰กexp{โˆ’๐‘Ÿ๐‘ก}๐‘†๐‘ก be the discounted value of the traded securities at time ๐‘ก. This process follows a martingale under the martingale measure, โ„š, since we have ๐‘‘ฬ€๐‘†๐‘ก=ฬ€๐‘†๐‘ก๐œŽ๐‘†๐‘‘๐‘Š๐‘ก๐‘†,โ„š,(4.14) where ๐‘‘๐‘Š๐‘ก๐‘†,โ„šโ‰ก๐‘‘๐‘Š๐‘†๐‘ก+๐œ†๐‘†๐‘‘๐‘ก is the increment to a โ„š-Brownian motion. Hence, we can write the Kunita-Watanabe decomposition of the discounted option payoff under โ„š: ๎€ทฮ›exp{โˆ’๐‘Ÿ๐‘ก}๐‘‡๎€ธโˆ’๐พ+=๐ป0+๎€œ๐‘‡0๐œ๐‘ก๐‘‘ฬ€๐‘†๐‘ก+๐‘‰๐ป๐‘‡,(4.15) where ๐‘‰๐ป is a โ„™-martingale orthogonal to ฬ€๐‘† under โ„š. Lรฉvyโ€™s Theorem shows that the process ๐™ฐ defined by ๐‘‘๐™ฐ๐‘ก=๐‘‘๐‘Šฮ›๐‘กโˆ’๐œŒ๐‘‘๐‘Š๐‘†๐‘กโˆš1โˆ’๐œŒ2(4.16) is a โ„™-Brownian motion and that it is independent of ๐‘Š๐‘†. Then, by Girsanovโ€™s theorem, (๐‘Š๐‘†,โ„š,๐™ฐ) also follows two-dimensional โ„š-Brownian motion. Since ๐‘‰๐ป is a martingale under โ„š and is orthogonal to ๐น, the martingale representation theorem shows that we have ๐‘‰๐ป๐‘ก=๐œ“๐‘‘๐™ฐ๐‘ก for some process ๐œ“. In particular, ๐‘‰๐ป is orthogonal under โ„™ to the martingale part of ฬ€๐‘†, where the martingale part of ฬ€๐‘† under โ„™ is defined as ๐บ๐‘ก=๎€œ๐‘ก0๐œŽ๐‘†๐‘†๐‘ ๐‘‘๐‘Š๐‘†๐‘ .(4.17) Next, we suppose that ๐‘ƒ๐‘ก=exp{โˆ’๐‘Ÿ(๐‘‡โˆ’๐‘ก)}๐”ผโ„š๎‚ƒ๎€ทฮ›๐‘‡๎€ธโˆ’๐พ+๎‚„.(4.18) Using (4.15) we obtain ๐‘ƒ๐‘ก๎‚ธ๐ป=exp{๐‘Ÿ๐‘ก}0+๎€œ๐‘ก0๐œ๐‘ ๐‘‘ฬ€๐‘†๐‘ +V๐ป๐‘ก๎‚น.(4.19) Consider now the non-self-financing strategy with value ฬ€ฮ ๐‘ก=๐‘ƒ๐‘ก and the number of securities given by ฬ€๐‘›๐‘†๐‘ก=๐œ๐‘ก. Given (4.1) and (4.19), we obtain that ๐‘‘ฬ€๐ถ๐‘ก=exp{๐‘Ÿ๐‘ก}๐‘‘๐‘‰๐ป๐‘ก. This shows that, ๐‘‰๐ป,ฬ€๐ถ is a โ„™-martingale orthogonal to ๐บ. We recall that a strategy (ฮ ,๐‘›๐‘†) is locally risk minimizing if and only if the associated cost process follows a โ„™-martingale orthogonal to ๐บ. Hence the strategy (ฬ€ฮ ,ฬ€๐‘›๐‘†) is locally risk minimizing.
We now prove an explicitly expression for the random variable ๐‘ƒ๐‘ก, which is called the minimum entropy price. The Black-Scholes formula implies that ๐‘ƒ๐‘ก๎€ท=๐ถ๐‘ก,ฮ›๐‘ก๎€ธ๐œ‡=exp๎€ฝ๎€ทฮ›โˆ’๐‘Ÿโˆ’๐œŽฮ›๐œŒ๐œ†๐‘†๎€ธฮ›(๐‘‡โˆ’๐‘ก)๎€พ๎€บ๐‘ก๐™ฝ๎€ท๐‘‘1๎€ธ๐œ‡,๐‘กโˆ’๐พexp๎€ฝ๎€ทฮ›โˆ’๐œŒ๐œŽฮ›๐œ†๐‘†๎€ธ๎€พ๐™ฝ๎€ท๐‘‘(๐‘‡โˆ’๐‘ก)2,,๐‘ก๎€ธ๎€ป(4.20) which can be written as a function ๐ถ(๐‘ก,ฮ›๐‘ก) of ๐‘ก and ฮ›๐‘ก. Using (4.19), we obtain that ๐œ๐‘ก=๐œŽฮ›ฮ›๐‘ก๐œŽ๐‘†๐‘†๐‘ก๐œŒ๐ถฮ›๎€ท๐‘ก,ฮ›๐‘ก๎€ธ.(4.21) The required expression for ฬ€๐‘›๐น๐‘ก follows immediately.

Our paper addresses the problem of dynamic bank provisioning for (illiquid) nonmarketable mortgages, ฮ›, for which substitute (liquid) marketable securities, ๐‘†, is part of the liquidity provisioning strategy. Due to the presence of cross-hedge liquidity risk we operate in an incomplete market setting. In this regard, we employ a non-self-financing strategy to ensure that uncertainty is reduced and trading is conducted in the Treasuries market. Moreover, the strategy is designed to influence a perfect replication at the cost of continuous cash infusion into the replicating bank portfolio. Since the cash infusion is random, the risk-averse agent would require that the total uncertainty involved over the remaining life of the mortgage be minimized. As a consequence, for 0โ‰ค๐‘กโ‰ค๐‘‡, the associated ex-ante aggregated liquidity risk is given by ๐š๐‘ก(ฮ˜)=๐”ผโ„™๎ƒฌ๎‚ต๎€œ๐‘‡๐‘กexp{โˆ’๐‘Ÿ(๐‘ โˆ’๐‘ก)}๐‘‘๐ถ๐‘ข๎‚ถ2๎ƒญ,0โ‰ค๐‘กโ‰ค๐‘‡.(4.22) Now โˆซ๐‘‡๐‘กexp{โˆ’๐‘Ÿ(๐‘ โˆ’๐‘ก)}๐‘‘๐ถ๐‘ข is stochastic, so we will focus on minimizing the risk in (4.5). We apply a local risk minimization criterion which entails that instead of minimizing the uncertainty with respect to the cash infusion, ๐ถ๐‘ก, over the process, the strategy attempts to minimize, at each date, the uncertainty over the next infinitesimal period. Also, the incompleteness entails the existence of infinitely many equivalent martingale measures. In order to determine the appropriate price of the asset value one should choose an appropriate equivalent martingale measure. In this case, the process is โ„š-Brownian motion so that the discounted price process exp{โˆ’๐‘Ÿ๐‘ก}๐‘†๐‘ก follows martingale pricing. The equivalent martingale measure will be determine according to the risk minimization criterion in Theorem 4.1. Let us consider the discounted price to be ๎€ทฮ›exp{โˆ’๐‘Ÿ๐‘ก}๐‘‡๎€ธโˆ’๐พ+.(4.23) Applying the Kunita-Watanabe decomposition for the discounted price under a measure โ„š, we get ๐พฮ =๐ป0+๎€œ๐‘‡0๐œ๐‘ก๐‘‘ฬ€๐‘†๐‘ข+๐‘‰๐ป๐‘‡,(4.24) where ๐‘‰๐ป is a โ„™-martingale orthogonal to ฬ€๐‘† under the measure โ„š. Let ๐‘ƒ๐‘ก=exp{โˆ’๐‘Ÿ(๐‘‡โˆ’๐‘ก)}๐”ผโ„š๐‘ก๎‚ƒ๎€ทฮ›๐‘‡๎€ธโˆ’๐พ+๎‚„(4.25) which can be rewritten as ๐‘ƒ๐‘ก๎‚ธ๐ป=exp{๐‘Ÿ๐‘ก}0+๎€œ๐‘ก0๐œ๐‘ข๐‘‘ฬ€๐‘†๐‘ข+๐ฟ๐ป๐‘ก๎‚น.(4.26)

4.3. Residual Aggregate Liquidity Risk

During the GFC, two types of uncertainty concerning liquidity requirements arose. Firstly, each individual bank was faced with idiosyncratic liquidity risk. At any given time its depositors may have more or less liquidity needs. Uncertainty also arose from the fact that banks face aggregate liquidity risk. In some periods aggregate liquidity demand is high while in others it is low. Thus, aggregate risk exposes all banks to the same shock, by increasing or decreasing the demand for liquidity that they face simultaneously. The ability of banks to hedge themselves against these liquidity risks crucially depend on the functioning, or, more precisely, the completeness of financial markets. The next theorem provides an explicit expression for the aggregate liquidity risk when a locally risk minimizing strategy is utilized in an incomplete market.

Theorem 4.2 (residual aggregate liquidity risk). The aggregate liquidity risk when a locally risk minimizing strategy at time ๐‘ก is implemented is equal to ๐š๐‘ก๐‘Ÿ๐‘š=๐œŽฮ›2๎€ท1โˆ’๐œŒ2๎€ธ๎€œ๐‘‡๐‘กexp{โˆ’2๐‘Ÿ(๐‘ โˆ’๐‘ก)}๐”ผโ„™๎‚ƒฮ›๐‘†2๐ถฮ›๎€ท๐‘ ,ฮ›๐‘ ๎€ธ2๎‚„๐‘‘๐‘ .(4.27) This can be approximated by ๐š๐‘ก๐‘Ÿ๐‘šโ‰ˆ๐œŽฮ›2(1โˆ’๐œŒ)2๐ถฮ›๎€ท0,ฮ›0๎€ธ2ฮ›201โˆ’exp{โˆ’2๐‘Ÿ(๐‘‡โˆ’๐‘ก)}.2๐‘Ÿ(4.28)

Proof. Let us now assume ฮฆ=ฮฆโ‹† and ฮ ๐‘ก=๐ถ(๐‘ก,ฮ›๐‘ก). Under โ„š, the wealth process, ฮ , evolves as ๐‘‘ฮ ๐‘ก=๐‘Ÿฮ ๐‘ก๐‘‘๐‘ก+๐œŒ๐œŽฮ›ฮ›๐‘ก๐ถฮ›๎€ท๐‘ก,ฮ›๐‘ก๎€ธ๐‘‘๐‘Š๐‘ก๐‘†,โ„šฬ€๐ถ+๐‘‘๐‘ก.(4.29) In addition, (exp{โˆ’๐‘Ÿ๐‘ก}๐ถ(๐‘ก,ฮ›๐‘ก))๐‘ก follows a โ„š-martingale, where ๎€ท๐‘‘๐ถ๐‘ก,ฮ›๐‘ก๎€ธ๎€ท=๐‘Ÿ๐ถ๐‘ก,ฮ›๐‘ก๎€ธ๐‘‘๐‘ก+๐ถฮ›๎€ท๐‘ก,ฮ›๐‘ก๎€ธ๐œŽฮ›ฮ›๐‘ก๐‘‘๐‘Š๐‘กฮ›,โ„š,(4.30)๐‘‘๐‘Š๐‘กฮ›,โ„š=๐‘‘๐‘Šฮ›๐‘ก+๐œŒ๐œ†๐‘†๐‘‘๐‘ก(4.31) defines a โ„š-Brownian motion. One can write it as ๐‘‘๐‘Š๐‘กฮ›,โ„š=๐‘‘๐‘Šฮ›๐‘กโˆ’๐œŒ๐‘‘๐‘Š๐‘†๐‘ก+๐œŒ๐‘‘๐‘Š๐‘ก๐‘†,โ„š=โˆš1โˆ’๐œŒ2๐‘‘๐‘Š2๐‘ก+๐œŒ๐‘‘๐‘Š๐‘กฮ›,โ„š.(4.32) Comparing (4.29) and (4.30) we obtain that exp{โˆ’๐‘Ÿ๐‘ก}๐‘‘๐ถ๐‘ก=exp{โˆ’๐‘Ÿ๐‘ก}๐ถฮ›๎€ท๐‘ก,ฮ›๐‘ก๎€ธ๐œŽฮ›ฮ›๐‘กโˆš1โˆ’๐œŒ2๐‘‘๐‘Š2๐‘ก,(4.33) hence (4.27).
In what follows, we let ๐›ฟ๐‘ก be the delta of the mortgage process at time ๐‘ก that is computed from the minimal entropy price so that ๐›ฟ๐‘ก=๐ถฮ›(๐‘ก,ฮ›๐‘ก). We must now compute ๐”ผโ„™[๐›ฟ2๐‘กฮ›2๐‘ก] for all ๐‘ก in [0,๐‘‡]. If (๐›ฟ2๐‘ก,ฮ›2๐‘ก)๐‘ก>0 were a martingale, the task would be easy since we would have ๐”ผโ„™[๐›ฟ2๐‘กฮ›2๐‘ก]=๐›ฟ20ฮ›20. But (๐›ฟ2๐‘กฮ›2๐‘ก)๐‘กโ‰ฅ0 is not a martingale. However, it can be shown that for small ๐œŽฮ›2๐‘‡, the expectation ๐”ผโ„™[๐›ฟ2๐‘กฮ›2๐‘ก] is approximated by the constant ๐›ฟ20ฮ›20. The formal proof follows from the fact that ๐”ผโ„™[๐›พ๐‘กฮ›2๐‘ก]โ‰ˆ๐›พ0ฮ›20,๐›พ๐‘ก=๐ถฮ›ฮ›(๐‘ก,ฮ›๐‘ก), denoting the gamma of the value of the asset. Therefore, we finally have that ๐œŽฮ›2๎€ท1โˆ’๐œŒ2๎€ธ๎€œ๐‘‡๐‘กexp{โˆ’2๐‘Ÿ๐‘ }๐”ผโ„™๎€บ๐›ฟ2๐‘ ฮ›๐‘†2๎€ป๐‘‘๐‘ โ‰ˆ๐œŽฮ›2๎€ท1โˆ’๐œŒ2๎€ธ๐›ฟ20ฮ›201โˆ’exp{โˆ’2๐‘Ÿ(๐‘‡โˆ’๐‘ก)}.2๐‘Ÿ(4.34)

Applying a non-self-financing strategy and considering ฬ€ฮ ๐‘ก=๐‘ƒ๐‘ก and ฬ€๐‘›๐‘†๐‘ก=๐œ๐‘ก, we obtain that ๐‘‘ฬ€๐ถ๐‘ก=exp{๐‘Ÿ๐‘ก}๐‘‘๐‘‰๐ป๐‘ก.(4.35) This implies that ฬ€๐ถ is โ„™-martingale orthogonal to ๐บ. In this regard, the strategy (ฮ ,๐‘›๐‘†) is locally risk minimizing if and only if the associated cost process ๐ถ(ฮ˜) follows a โ„™-martingale orthogonal to ๐บ. This means the strategy minimizes at each date the uncertainty over the next infinitesimal period. In applying the risk-minimization strategy there remains some โ€œresidualโ€ aggregate liquidity risk stemming from the imperfection of the Brownian motion processes ๐‘Š๐‘† and ๐‘Šฮ›. After the bank has implemented the locally risk minimizing strategy at time ๐‘ก, the aggregate liquidity risk is ๐š๐‘ก๐‘Ÿ๐‘š=๐œŽฮ›2๎€ท1โˆ’๐œŒ2๎€ธ๎€œ๐‘‡๐‘กexp{โˆ’2๐‘Ÿ(๐‘ โˆ’๐‘ก)}๐”ผโ„™๎‚ƒฮ›2๐ถฮ›๎€ท๐‘†,ฮ›๐‘ข๎€ธ2๎‚„.(4.36) For ๐›ฟ๐‘ก associated with the value process at time ๐‘ก computed via the minimized entropy price, we now need to compute ๐”ผโ„™[๐›ฟ2๐‘ก,ฮ›2๐‘ก] for all ๐‘ก in [0,๐‘‡]. Since ๐”ผโ„™[๐›ฟ2๐‘ก,ฮ›2๐‘ก] is approximated by the constant ๐›ฟ20ฮ›20, then ๐”ผโ„™[๐›พ๐‘กฮ›2๐‘ก]โ‰ˆ๐›พ0ฮ›2๐‘ก, ๐›พ๐‘ก=๐ถฮ›(๐‘ก,ฮ›๐‘ก) which is the gamma of the mortgage value. Therefore, the residual liquidity risk at time ๐‘ก is ๐œŽฮ›2(1โˆ’๐œŒ)2๎€œ๐‘‡๐‘กexp{โˆ’2๐‘Ÿ๐‘ }๐”ผโ„™๎€บ๐›ฟ2๐‘ขฮ›๐‘†๐‘ข๎€ป๐‘‘๐‘ขโ‰ˆ๐œŽฮ›2(1โˆ’๐œŒ)2๐›ฟ20ฮ›20โˆ’exp{โˆ’2๐‘Ÿ(๐‘‡โˆ’๐‘ก)}.2๐‘Ÿ(4.37)

5. Conclusions and Future Directions

In this paper, we discuss liquidity risk management for banks. We investigate the stochastic dynamics of bank items such as loans, reserves, securities, deposits, borrowing and bank capital (compare with Question 1). In accordance with Basel III, our paper proposes that overall liquidity risk is best analyzed using ratio analysis approaches. Here, liquidity risk is measured via the LCR. In this case, we provide numerical results to highlight some important issues. Our numerical quantitative model shows that a low LCR stems from a low level of liquid assets or high nett cash outflows (compare with Question 2). Moreover, we provide a characterization of liquidity risk provisioning by considering an (illiquid) nonmarketable mortgage as an underlying asset and using (liquid) marketable securities for provisioning. In this case, we use non-self-financing strategy that considers market incompleteness to provision for liquidity risk. Then, we provide a quantitative framework for assessing residual risk stemming from the above strategy (compare with Question 3).

Future research should focus on other features of the GFC that are related to liquidity provisioning. The first involves the decrease in prices of AAA-rated tranches of structured financial products below fundamental values. The second is the effect of the GFC on interbank markets for term funding and collateralized money markets. Thirdly, further investigations should address the fear of contagion should a major institution fail. Finally, the effects on the real economy should be considered. In addition, the stochastic dynamic model we have consider in this paper does not take assets and liabilities with residual maturities into account. Such a model should be developed.

Appendices

A. More about Liquidity Risk

In this section, we provide more information about measures by cash flow, liquidity monitoring approaches, liquidity risk ratings and national approaches to liquidity risk.

A.1. Measures by Cash Flow

Banks use the intensity of the cash flow to predict the level of stress events. In this case, we determine the level of both cash in flows and cash out flows depending on both supply and demand for liquidity in the normal market performance. In this regard, the bank cash flow predicts the level of stress event ๐‘ . Moreover, the use of proforma is an acceptable standard which determine the uses and sources of funds in the bank. It identifies where the bank funding short fall and liquidity gap lies.

A.2. Liquidity Monitoring Approaches

The BCBS has set international standards for sound management of liquidity risk. In this regard, the monitoring and evaluation of the banks operational activities is an internal control measure. However, the monitoring approach is divided into three levels, that is, the liquid assets approach, the cash flow approach, and a mixture of both. Liquid asset approach is mostly appropriate used in the Treasury bond market. In this regard, banks are required to maintain some liquid asset in their balance sheet that could be used during the hard period. Assets such as government securities are appropriate to maintain in the balance sheet because they can easily enable the bank to secure funding through securitization. While Cash flow matching approach enable banks to match the cash in flows with the cash out flows from the balance sheet activities.

The monitoring approaches for assessing liquidity risk is divided into three classes, that is, liquid asset approach, the cash flow approach and the combination of both. In the liquid asset approach a bank prescribed to a minimum level of cash or high-quality liquid or marketable assets in relation to the deposits and other sources of funds. While maturity mismatch classify the expected inflows and outflows of funds into time bands of their residual maturity.

A.3. Liquidity Risk Rating

The rating of liquidity risk is categorized into two sets of indicators, that is, the quantitative and qualitative liquidity risk indicators.

Table 4 shows the quantitative and qualitative liquidity risk indicators. In light of the above, the rating for quantitative liquidity risk management is classified into three levels, that is, low, moderate level, and high level of liquidity risk. Therefore, a bank with a full set of all the indicated quantitative indicators has a low level of liquidity risk. Moreover, the rating for qualitative liquidity risk is divided into three levels, that is, strong, satisfactory, and weak quality of management of liquidity risk. In the above, we indicated that rating of liquidity risk is divided into two sets of indicators, namely, the quantitative liquidity risk indicators and qualitative liquidity risk indicators. According to Table 4, a bank with a full set of all the indicated qualitative indicators has a low level of liquidity risk, while a bank with a full set of all indicated qualitative indicators has a higher level of liquidity risk management.

A.4. National Approaches to Liquidity Risk

In this section, we discuss a useful principle which needs to be developed by individual countries to ensure sound management of liquidity risk and appropriate level of liquidity insurance by banks. This principle could be enforced via policies that assess liquidity as an internal measure; stress testing and other scenario analysis which determine the probability of a bank culminating into liquidity crisis; contingency funding to provide reliable sources of funds to cover the short fall; setting limitations such as holding of liquid assets, minimum liquid assets, limits on maturity mismatches, and limits on a particular funding sources; reporting about liquidity risks and sources of liquidity as well as through public disclosure to enable investors to access bank information.