Abstract

This paper first introduces the allocative and profit efficiency in the presence of the negative data and then presents a new circular index to measure the productivity change of decision making units (DMUs) for the case that the dataset contains the inputs and/or outputs with the negative values in data envelopment analysis (DEA). The proposed index is decomposed into four components in the two stages. The range directional model (RDM) and the proposed efficiencies are used to compute the proposed index and its components. The interpretations of the components are presented. Finally, a numerical example is organized to illustrate the proposed index and its components at three successive periods of time.

1. Introduction

The Malmquist productivity index which measures the productivity change over time was introduced by Caves et al. [1]. Fare et al. [2] developed the Malmquist productivity index that was based on data envelopment analysis (DEA). The Malmquist index can be applied in many fields [3, 4]. By using Malmquist index, the productivity growth can be decomposed into the efficiency change and technical change components. The second component measures the shift in the technology frontier.

Pastor and Lovell [5] suggested the global Malmquist productivity index that is circular and can be decomposed into the circular components. The global index and the meta-Malmquist index developed in Portela and Thanassoulis [6]. In addition, Hosseinzadeh Lotfi et al. developed the new ideas about Malmquist index in [7, 8].

Maniadakis and Thanassoulis [9] assumed the input cost vector is known and suggested the cost Malmquist index. Tohidi et al. [10] extended the cost Malmquist index into the profit Malmquist index that is used when the input cost and the output price vector are available. Then, Tohidi and Razavyan [11] proposed the global profit Malmquist index. The cost Malmquist index was also developed in Tohidi et al. [12] and is called the global cost Malmquist productivity index.

Sometimes in the process of production negative inputs and/or outputs may occur. For example, DMUs may generate undesirable outputs. In such a case, negative values can be considered for these undesirable outputs. Instances of systems with negative inputs and/or outputs are explained in [13, 14]. The traditional DEA models can be applied to compute the Malmquist index with the nonnegative data. They cannot deal with the negative data. Portela et al. [15] presented an approach named the range directional model (RDM) and solved this problem. They calculated the meta-Malmquist index using the RDM model in Portela and Thanassoulis [16].

To investigate the productivity change of DMUs with the negative data, this paper defines the profit and allocative efficiency and introduces an index to measure the productivity changes of DMUs when some inputs and/or outputs are negative and the costs of inputs and the prices of outputs are available. Then, the proposed index is decomposed into some components in the two stages. The range directional model (RDM) and the proposed efficiencies are used to compute the proposed index and its components.

The current paper unfolds as follows. Section 2 describes the RDM. In Section 3 the global Malmquist productivity index is expressed. Section 4 defines the profit and the allocative efficiency for the DMUs with some negative inputs and outputs and then suggests a new index. The decomposition and the theorem of circularity property of the proposed index and its components are presented in Section 5. Section 6 prepares some DEA models to compute the proposed index and its components. Section 7 provides a numerical example. Section 8 concludes.

2. The Range Directional Model

Portela et al. [15] introduced the RDM to compare DMUs under the negative data. Assume that, in time period () and unit consumes an input vector to produce an output vector . We consider an ideal point (IP) for the time period with the minimum inputs and the maximum outputs observed in this time period, where for each input () and is as and for each output () throughout is as and the directional vector is as . In the RDM this directional vector for in time period is as ; and ; that reflects the ranges of possible improvement for this DMU. The RDM for in time period for the case of the VRS technology is as follows (Portela et al., 2004):

The value of in model (1) is an inefficiency measure and the RDM efficiency measure of unit is that is defined as if at the optimal solution to model (1) a binding constraint corresponds to input or if a binding constraint corresponds to output . and are the target inputs and target outputs in time , respectively. It is clear that the upper bound of is 1.

3. The Global Profit Malmquist Productivity Index

The global profit Malmquist index () is applied to measure the productivity changes of DMUs when the input costs and output prices are available. Assume that, in time period ,  (), the input cost vector is and the output price vector is ; by using these vectors the common input cost vector and the common output price vector can be defined, respectively, as , , and , where the weights and () are the decision-makers’ preferences over and (), respectively [12].

This paper uses the definition of profit [13] to compute the global profit and the observed profit of with the negative data. The observed profit of under the cost and price vectors of time period can be calculated as and the maximum profit of time under the price vector of this time is defined as . The set of activities which corresponds to the scalar defines the profit boundary of time as . In this case the index for the DMUs with the nonnegative data is defined as follows: where and is the global production technology [5]. The term is the observed profit of under the common price vectors and . The ratio in the denominator of is the reciprocal to measure of the profit efficiency introduced in Cooper et al. [13] for under the common price vectors. This ratio measures the distance between the observed profit and the common profit boundary and will have a minimum value of 1. A value greater than 1 of index indicates the productivity regress and a value less than 1 implies the productivity progress between and . A value of 1 indicates that the productivity remains unchanged. Because of the limitations of the DEA models with the negative inputs and outputs [17, 18], we cannot investigate the productivity change of DMUs with the negative data by using tradition Malmquist indices. To this end, the next section proposes an appropriate global profit Malmquist index when some inputs or/and outputs are negative.

4. The Global Profit Malmquist Index with the Negative Data

In this section we assume that there are some negative inputs and/or negative outputs and evaluate the productivity changes of DMUs by using the index under the VRS technology. We denote the profit of the ideal point of time period by that the superscript on indicates the profit is computed under the cost and the price vectors of time . By using the definition of the profit, we will have

Now we define the profit and allocative efficiency of a DMU with the negative data.

Definition 1. The measure of the profit efficiency for under the price vectors of time is as

By using (3) it is clear that the value of is equal to or less than one. As the profit efficiency is less than 1 it may be because production takes place at the wrong input and/or output mix in light of the input costs and the output prices; this is captured by using the measure of the allocative efficiency which is defined as follows.

Definition 2. Let be the target DMU of in time period using RDM. The allocative efficiency of can be defined as follows:

If profit efficiency is less than 1 and it is because production is based on excessive input or shortage output usage, we can capture it by using the RDM efficiency measure that was denoted by .

To define the index under the VRS technology in the presence of the negative datawe first consider a global ideal point (GIP) defined over the global technology that, for input , and output (, is as and , respectively. This ideal point is used for computing the range for observed in time . The component of is , , and component of is . Now we define the index in the presence of the negative data as follows: where is the profit of the global ideal point and the superscript indicates that the profit of this point is computed under the common price vectors and . The ratio is the profit efficiency defined in Definition 1 under the common cost and price vectors. When the index has the value greater than 1, it means that the productivity of unit has improved from the time to . The productivity has declined when the value of the index is below 1 and remains unchanged if . The index is circular and it can be decomposed into four circular components as shown in the next section.

5. Decomposition of the Index

In the first stage the index is decomposed into two and as follows:

The term outside the brackets in the right-hand side of (7) represents the profit efficiency change () component of the unit under evaluation from to and the term inside the brackets provides the profit frontier shift (the technical change) between the periods and under the VRS production technologies of two times t and (). The and components of the index can themselves be decomposed.

The Decomposition of the . The component can be decomposed into two components as follows:where and are the profit of the global point under the costs and prices of the periods and , respectively. The first ratio in the right-hand side of (8) is the allocative efficiency change () components of the index; and the second ratio is the RDM within-period-efficiency change () of the unit that is under evaluation from to ; the RDM within-period-efficiency change was introduced by Portela et al. [15].

The Decomposition of . We can decompose the into two components as follows:

The first term in the above decomposition measures the frontier shift between the VRS frontiers of times and and the technical change (), along the ray [16]. The second term is a residual price effect () part. The numerical values of the components of the index obtained in this section are interpreted in the similar manner as the index itself; a value below 1 indicates regress, greater than 1 indicates progress, and 1 indicates that performance stayed constant.

5.1. The Circularity Property of and All of Its Components

Circularity is a prominent property of the index and all of its components in the presence of the negative data. To show this property, the following theorem is stated.

Theorem 3. For every DMUj (), in three successive periods,(1) (the circularity of ),(2) (the circularity of ),(3) (the circularity of ),(4) (the circularity of ),(5) (the circularity of ),(6) (the circularity of ),(7) (the circularity of ),
where, for instance, () is the profit Malmquist changes between periods and for .

Proof. For instance, let be the profit Malmquist changes between periods and for . Therefore,
In other words, the global profit Malmquist change from period to is the product of the successive global profit Malmquist change from period to and from the period to . Similarly, we can show that all of the components are circular.

The above properties show that in the presence of the negative data the index and its components are appropriate indices in the fact that they link in clear way productivity change indices over successive time periods.

6. The Computation of the Proposed Index and Its Components

This section prepares some DEA models to compute the index and its components. The observed profit is computed as . Similarly, the observed profits denoted by , , and are, respectively, , , and . We can compute for unit by using the following model: Similarly, we will have

The term can be computed by using model (11) after replacing the time period with .

For computing that is equal to we first calculate by using model (1) after replacing and with and , respectively. Similarly, we can compute the value of after replacing the time period with . In order to compute , we first extend model (1) for the case that the production technology formed from all DMUs observed in all time periods . The proposed model is shown in (13). In fact, the optimal value of model (13), , is an inefficiency of along direction under the global production technology :

iscomputed using model (13) after replacing the time period with .

By replacing the values obtained from the above models in the formulations of index and its components, the values of them can be computed. A value greater than 1 of index and its components indicates the regress and a value less than 1 implies the progress between periods and . A value equal to 1 indicates that there is not any change between two time periods.

7. Numerical Example

This section illustrates the property of and its components, for example, the circularity property, using a numerical example. Table 1 shows units DMU1–DMU4 with one input (I) and two outputs (O1 and O2) and their cost () and prices ( and ) for 3 successive periods.

To compute the indices and their components by using the data in Table 1, suppose that the preferences about the input costs and output prices are available and have been specified by decision-makers as (). Therefore, the common costs and prices are obtained by using the decision-makers’ preferences:

By using the data of periods 1, 2, and 3, the inputs and the outputs of the global ideal point will be 2, −1, and 7, respectively.

Table 2 shows , , and of all of the DMUs for , , and . For instance, the columns 2, 3, and 4 in Table 2 show , , and , respectively. For DMU2, as an example, we have . That is, the productivity of DMU2 in period 2 is more than its productivity in period 1 and hence the productivity has been improved from the time period 1 to 2.

According to , the productivity of DMU2 in period 3 is less than its productivity in period 2. By the circularity property of the profit Malmquist change, we can conclude that .

Looking at the average values in Table 2, for example, we can see that the average global profit Malmquist index of all of the DMUs from the first period to the second period (1.0298) is higher than their average global profit Malmquist index from the second period to the third period (1.0037). The average of columns 2, 3, and 4 in Table 2 shows that the average growth of all of the DMUs from the first period to the third period is less than their growth from period 1 to period 2 and that from period 2 to period 3. A similar discussion can be made for the other columns of Table 2.

Tables 3 and 4 illustrate the results from the RDM within-period-efficiency change, allocative efficiency change, the frontier shift between the VRS frontiers, and residual price change from different periods to the periods 2 and 3, and the averages are shown in the last row of these tables.

For example, the frontier shift between the VRS frontiers along the ray from period 1 to period 2 is 0.6064; that is, there is a decrease in technical progress for DMU1 from period 1 to period 2.

Using the average values in Table 4, for example, we can see that the average frontier shifts between the VRS frontiers along the rays , , , and of all of the DMUs from the first period to the second period (0.862) are less than their average frontier shifts between the VRS frontiers along the rays , , , and from the second period to the third period (1.1366). The value , for DMU2 as an example, for the component, indicates that the effect of input cost changes from the first period to the second period is detrimental to productivity.

8. Conclusions

Under the VRS assumption allocative and profit efficiencies have been defined for the case that the dataset contains the inputs and/or outputs with the negative values in data envelopment analysis. The definitions could be generalized when the unit cost of the ith input or the unit price of the th output of all of DMUs is different. The proposed index decomposed into some components in two stages. The RDM and the defined efficiencies were used to compute the proposed index and its components. The interpretations of the components were presented. A numerical example has been presented for three successive periods of time to illustrate the properties of and its components in the presence of the negative inputs and outputs.

Conflict of Interests

The authors declare that there is no conflict of interests regarding the publication of this paper.

Acknowledgment

Financial support of this research, in a project entitled An Overall Index to Determine the Progress or Regress of the Productivity of DMUs and Its Global Form in the Presence of the Negative Data, Islamic Azad University, Central Tehran Branch, is acknowledged.