Abstract

This paper analyzes the impact of capacity drop on commuters’ travel choice behaviors under uncertainty. For clarity, we assume that the capacity drop is triggered by the queue forming at the bottleneck under the hypercongestion circumstances, and the stochasticity of the drop could not be neglected. Considering the uncertainty of travel time, we establish a bottleneck model with commuters choosing their departure time according to the mean travel cost. From the proposed model, analytical solutions are achieved and therefore several properties are presented, including monotonicity of travel cost and departure rate, and the relationship between dispersion degree and length of peak period. To alleviate traffic congestion at the bottleneck and avoid capacity drop, we design a time-varying toll scheme and a step toll scheme. Evolution of queue length in equilibrium is discussed based on the Laih model. Numerical examples are also presented to demonstrate the established model and the effectiveness of the proposed toll schemes.

1. Introduction

Capacity plays one key role in the commuting systems, and the capacity drop phenomenon attracts much research from the field of transportation. As presented by empirical studies, the self-organized capacity drop could be observed in bottlenecks at many locations. For instance, by observation in and near Toronto, Canada, Cassidy and Bertini [1] reported that the average rate discharge from a queue could be 10% lower than the flows measured prior to queue’s formation. Latterly, Zhang and Levinson [2] observed 3-12% capacity drop on freeway bottlenecks in Twin Cities area, Minnesota. In addition, self-organized capacity drop phenomenon is also observed in a bottleneck located in the Twin Cities west metropolitan region by Srivastava and Geroliminis [3].

Though most of the existing literature on capacity drop in bottlenecks is from deterministic perspective, there is some research suggested that the self-organized capacity drop does not always occur at a fixed flow rate and is intrinsically stochastic. It is even pointed out that that capacity of a bottleneck could be defined as a function of breakdown probability [4, 5]. In fact, the stochastic properties may not be limited in the self-organized capacity drop phenomenon. For example, the capacity could fluctuate from day to day and could be treated as a stochastic one [6]. Based on the consideration, this paper is to investigate the impact of capacity drop at a bottleneck in a stochastic circumstance.

The analysis of this paper is based on the classical bottleneck model, which is originally developed by Vickrey [7]. The model could formulate commuters’ trip schedule and was recognized as a useful tool for modeling the queuing behaviors at a bottleneck during the morning peak. In literature, many studies have extended the basic bottleneck model from different aspects, like considering the case of elastic demand [8] and commuters’ heterogeneity [9, 10]. Specifically, the influences of various impact factors on the performance of commuting systems are discussed too. For example, Lindsey [11] investigated the effects of information provision under stochastic bottleneck capacity conditions. van den Berg and Verhoef [12] studied the influence of commuters’ value of time on the efficiency of the commuting system. By considering the provision of parking spaces, Arnott et al. [13] examined the effects of parking availability on the commuting systems and evaluated the efficiency of road tolls and parking fees. Latterly, Qian et al. [14, 15] considered various impact factors including parking capacity allocations, parking fees and access times for traffic congestion mitigation, and total social costs reduction. In addition, extensions of bottlenecks could also be found like day-to-day travel behavior evolution [16], preference of autonomous vehicle users [17], and travel choice of shared-riders [18, 19]. Highly correlated with the work in this paper, Fosgerau and Small [20] investigated the bottleneck model with variable capacity in the rush hour in the hypercongestion environment. However, the authors discussed the commuters’ travel choice behavior under deterministic circumstances.

Besides the works on deterministic bottleneck model, the commuting systems are also discussed in stochastic environments. Fosgerau [21] derived a closed form expression for the expected cost in a bottleneck model with stochastic capacity and demand. Latterly, Fosgerau [22] presented characterization of how the expected delay and the variance of delay are related in a congested facility with random capacity and demand. Li et al. [23] analyzed the departure time choice behavior under stochastic capacity using Vickrey bottleneck model and developed numerical methods to solve a bottleneck where daily capacity follows a uniform distribution. Siu et al. [24] considered equilibrium trip scheduling under random travel delay in commuting system at rush hours. They found that random delay plays a significant role in travel costs and introduces substantial differences in the queuing pattern, departure, and arrival times. Xiao et al. [6] studied the bottleneck model with stochastic capacity with a uniform distribution; both analytical and numerical results show that the capacity variability of bottleneck leads to significant changes in departure time patterns. Xiao et al. [25, 26] extended the stochastic bottleneck model to heterogeneous values of time for studying the heterogeneous travelers’ departure time choice behavior. Furthermore, commuters depart at the same time can experience early or late arrival depending on the capacity in the stochastic circumstances. Furthermore, the impact of stochastic capacity at the downstream bottleneck after a merge is also investigated by Xiao et al. [25, 26].

As the capacity drop degrades the performance of the commuting system, researchers also tried to find approaches for alleviate the efficiency loss caused by capacity drop. Among the proposed approaches, ramp metering is proved to be effective for enhancing the dropped capacity [2, 27]. In addition, variable speed limit seems to work also [28], at least at the theoretical level. However, there are many methods to eliminate the queue and decrease the externality cost of the commuting system, which are toll based schemes. As a seed work, Arnott et al. [29] discussed the time-varying toll scheme together with the step toll scheme for higher efficiency in a commuting system. Compared with the time-varying toll schemes which are not easy to implement, the step toll schemes are much more practical and were studied by many researchers [30, 31]. In the step toll schemes, some fixed pricing toll charges are set during time intervals. Commuter in front of the queue need to pay the charges according to the time intervals. In the single-step toll scheme proposed by Arnott et al. [29] which is called ADL model, the arrival period is affected and the total private travel cost is found to be higher than that in the no-toll equilibrium. Furthermore, to achieve equilibrium, a mass of individuals depart just after the toll is lifted. Laih [32] proposed a single-step toll scheme called Laih model. Under the assumption that there are separate queuing facilities where commuters can wait and no mass departures are needed when the toll comes, the arrival times and the total travel cost may not be affected by the toll scheme. By considering the case in which drivers have an incentive to wait for the toll decrement if the waiting cost is less than the amount of toll saved, Lindsey et al. [30] presented a single-step toll scheme called braking model. In the model, the bottleneck is idle for a certain period in equilibrium; thus the peak period will be prolonged and higher total travel cost could be expected. Besides the toll scheme, there is another approach to enhance the efficiency of the commuting system from economic perspective, which is credit scheme. It is proved theoretically that the tradable credit schemes are able to gain the same efficiency that toll scheme could achieve [3335].

Based on the fact and above studies, we investigate the impact of stochastic capacity drop on commuters’ departure time choice behavior in this paper by deriving the analysis solution at equilibrium state. For convenience, it is assumed that the bottleneck capacity will drop by a stochastic amount when the queue at the bottleneck reaches a certain level, i.e., the capacity of bottleneck becomes stochastic after the queue length exceeds the certain level. Such kind of changes in capacity of bottleneck will yield different trip costs and inevitably affect the departure time choice behavior of the commuters. Furthermore, we design a time-varying toll to avoid capacity drop by eliminating queue. Because the time-varying toll is practically difficult to employ, here we also propose a step toll scheme to avoid capacity drop associated with a bottleneck.

The rest of this paper is organized as follows. Section 2 formulates the commuters’ travel costs and departure time choice in a bottleneck and reports the closed form solution and properties of the proposed model. Impacts of the stochastic capacity drop are discussed analytically. Section 3 presents both the time-varying toll scheme and the step toll scheme to avoid capacity drop for efficiency improvement. In Section 4, numerical examples are presented and sensitivity analysis is conducted. Finally, Section 5 concludes the paper.

2. The Bottleneck Model with Stochastic Capacity Drop

2.1. The Basic Model

The basic model could be seen as a simplification of the work by Vickrey [7]. Assume that there is a fixed number () of commuters from residential district to the Central Business District (CBD) through a highway with a single bottleneck. Since the bottleneck capacity is limited in the morning rush hour, if the commuters’ departure rate exceeds the capacity , a queue forms at the bottleneck. For any commuter traveling from residential location to the CBD, the travel time contains two parts, which are queuing time and free flow travel time of highway . For simplicity, it is assumed that . For all commuters, the preferred arrival time (work start time) is set to be ; one faces a schedule delay cost no matter he or she arrives early or late. We assume the departure rate at time point is and the earliest departure time is .

As there are a lot of symbols with various of subscripts in the paper, a table that summarizes all used notations is presented as an appendix (see the appendix).

The cumulative departures could be formulated as

In the morning rush hour, the capacity of the bottleneck is fully utilized from time and the length (in vehicles) of the queue is

Therefore, the queuing time for commuters depart at time is

The total cost could be seen as the sum of the travel time cost and schedule delay cost:where , , and are the values of travel time, schedule delay early (SDE), and schedule delay late (SDL). In accordance with empirical finding by Small (1982), we assume for the existence and uniqueness of the equilibrium.

At equilibrium, no commuter can reduce his or her travel cost by unilaterally altering his or her departure time; i.e., . Then the departure rate during the rush hour iswhere is the departure time at which an individual arrives at the CBD on time and is the ending time of the rush hour period. Because all commuters incur the same cost, and the duration of the peak is N/s, we can deduce that

The commuter’s travel cost at equilibrium could also be obtained by looking at the first commuter:

The longest queue at equilibrium is

2.2. Problem Settings and Assumptions

In this paper, we assume that the capacity of the single bottleneck will drop when the queue at the bottleneck reaches a certain level, denoted as ; thus there are basically two stages during the rush hour. Before the capacity drop occurs, the capacity of bottleneck is relatively high and stable. Let be the capacity of the bottleneck during the first stage. As the queue length exceeds the critical length , the second stage begins, and during the second stage, the capacity drops down stochastically. The dropped capacity of the bottleneck could be seen as a stochastic variable and follows a uniform distribution within interval , where , , representing the percentage of the remaining capacity, and , representing the lowest rate of available capacity. Let be the probability density function of the capacity; it follows that

In addition, we present the basic assumptions listed below:

(1) Commuters are homogeneous with the same values of travel time and schedule delays.

(2) Once the capacity has dropped, it would not recover until the queue dissipates. Then the intermediate travelers who are already in the queue should keep on waiting and passing through the bottleneck.

(3) At the second stage, the capacity of the bottleneck is constant within a day but fluctuates from day to day [6].

(4) Commuters are aware of the capacity drop probability, and their departure time choice follows the user equilibrium principle in terms of mean travel cost.

2.3. Formulation of the Bottleneck Model with Capacity Drop

Under the above conditions, the commuters’ travel cost is not always deterministic; commuters are assumed to make departure time decisions according to the mean trip cost. For simplicity, we set the preferred arrival time equal to . The mean travel cost with respect to departure time could be formulated asHere and are the schedule delay early and late for commuters departing at time , whereand

We consider a very congested rush hour, in which commuters always queue behind the bottleneck. As assumed above, at the first stage, the capacity of the bottleneck is deterministic; thus once the departure time is chosen by a commuter, his or her travel time and schedule delay are both deterministic. At the second stage, due to the stochasticity of the capacity, commuters departing at the same time may endure schedule delay early or late in different days. They may or may not encounter queuing delays randomly. For the complexity of the commuter’s choice behaviors, the rush hour could be divided into five departure intervals to characterize the different travel choice behaviors as listed below:(I)Commuters always arrive early and pass the bottleneck before the capacity drop.(II)Commuters always arrive early and pass the bottleneck after the capacity drop.(III)Depending on capacity commuters can arrive early or late.(IV)Commuters always arrive late and incur a queuing delay.(V)Commuters always arrive late and, depending on capacity, may or may not incur a queuing delay.

Here we use , , , and to denote the time points that separate the five situations. For clarity, here we assume that commuters queuing at length exactly do not suffer the capacity drop, which means the capacity drop begins after the commuters queuing at time point with length passed the bottleneck. For convenience, let denote the time point at which the capacity drops and the queue length reach at time point . it follows that

As the equilibrium condition for commuters’ departure time choice is that no commuter can reduce their mean trip cost by unilaterally altering his or her departure time, the five situations under the user equilibrium scheme could be summarized as follows.

Situation I. Commuters always arrive early in , and commuters departing at this interval will pass the bottleneck before the bottleneck capacity drops.
The departure rate is derived by differentiating (10) and setting the derivative as zero; i.e.,The departure rate in this interval iswhere is the earliest departure time. The boundary condition for this situation is that the cumulative number of departures by time reaches ; that means

Situation II. Commuters always arrive early in , and commuters departing at this interval will pass the bottleneck after the bottleneck capacity drops.
Using the equilibrium condition, we can obtain the departure rate in this interval:When the capacity of the bottleneck at the second stage is , . Thus we have

Situation III. Depending on capacity, commuters can arrive early or late in .
If the capacity of the bottleneck at the second stage is , no commuters experience schedule delay late. If the capacity of the bottleneck at the second stage is , no commuters experience schedule delay early. In other cases, i.e., where the capacity of the bottleneck is distributed stochastically within the interval , either schedule delay early or late may occur. If commuters departing at time point arrive at their workplaces on time, the corresponding capacity isThe departure rate in this interval iswhereWhen the capacity of the bottleneck at the second stage is , . Thus we have

Situation IV. Commuters always arrive late and incur a queuing delay in .
Using the equilibrium condition, we can obtain the departure rate within this interval is:The boundary condition for this situation isThat means the queuing length at time instant is 0, if the capacity at the second stage is .

Situation V. Commuters always arrive late and, depending on capacity, may or may not incur a queuing delay in .
For any time instant in , there is a watershed capacity of the bottleneck such that the queuing length equals zeros; i.e., ; the corresponding watershed capacity isWe then get the departure rate in this interval:The boundary condition for this situation is , and we could also haveSince are the ending times of the rush hour period, there is no more departure after that; we have , and From (13) and (27) we haveThe mean trip cost is identical for all commuters, so . Thus, we haveandHereUsing the boundary conditions and (13), we can obtainwhereThe equilibrium cumulative departure and arrival curves are shown in Figure 1. From the figure, one can confirm that at the beginning, the departure rate is constant and then exceeds the capacity so that a queue forms; the last commuter who departs at time point will be the last one who passes the bottleneck before capacity drops, and commuters departing after that one will pass the bottleneck after the capacity drops. Under the influence of capacity drop, the departure rate after has a decrease but remains constant until . When the capacity equals , commuters departing at time instant will arrive at CBD on time. Then the departure rate gradually decreases until . For commuters departing at time pint , the capacity which equals will make the commuters arrive on time. Thereafter, commuters arrive late, the departure rate will remain constant until , and the departure rate continues to decrease until 0 at the last departure interval .

2.4. Properties of the Watershed Bottleneck Model

To reveal interesting properties of the proposed bottleneck model and understand the impact of the stochastic capacity drop, here we present the following theorems.

Theorem 1. At equilibrium, the expected trip cost is a strictly monotonically increasing function of the travel demand.

Proof. At equilibrium, the expected trip cost is identical for all commuters. Since and , we haveBecause , it is easy to conclude ; then . Therefore, the expected trip cost is a strictly monotonically increasing function of the travel demand.

For the departure rate and cumulative departures, the following two theorems could be presented.

Theorem 2. At equilibrium, the departure rate is a monotonically decreasing function of the departure time , .

Proof. The theorem coincides with Theorem 2 in Xiao et al. [33] or Proposition 3 in Lindsey [36].

Theorem 3. The following inequality holds:

Proof. Since the queue may exist during , we haveAdditionally, the departure rate is nonnegative, so we haveand, on the other hand, since the queue may not exist during , holds.

For the impact of the stochasticity of capacity drop, the following theorem presents some analytical results.

Theorem 4. When the value of the parameter is increasing, the length of peak period will decrease.

Proof. From (30), the length of peak period isSince is a monotonically increasing function of and as denominator, is a monotonically decreasing function of .

Next, we discuss the effect of the capacity drop on equilibrium departures.

Theorem 5. At equilibrium, the departure rates and are dependent on the critical queue length .

Proof. Because is the solution to the nonlinear equation (20) and according to (16), the critical queue length is increasing with respect to ; hence is dependent on the critical queue length .
Similarly, based on (26), the departure rate is dependent on the critical queue length .

The departure rates , , and are constant, and they are independent of the critical queue length .

Theorem 6. At equilibrium, the expected trip cost is a strictly monotonically decreasing function of the critical queue length .

Proof. The first order derivative of the expected trip cost with respect to isTo prove , we need only to proveThe first order derivative of the left term of (44) with respect to isThen at point , term reaches its maximum, and the maximum is , so holds.

Theorem 7. With a fixed number of commuters and assuming that capacity drop would happen, the length of the morning peak period is shorter when the critical queue length is larger, and vice versa.

Proof. According to (28), the length of the morning peak period is as follows: Since , then ; we have . Therefore, the length of peak period is monotonically decreasing with respect to .

The above three theorems confirm the influence of capacity drop. Briefly, the length of the morning peak period is longer and the expected trip cost of all travelers is larger if the critical queue length is shorter. In fact, the length of first stage is as follows:

so decreasing the critical queue length is equivalent to the capacity drop taking place earlier.

2.5. Possible Equilibrium Traffic Flow Patterns

As shown in Figure 2, the other two possible departure patterns can happen, which depend on the critical queue length . The details of the two possible departure patterns are given as follows:

Case 1 in Figure 2(a). Three situations (i.e., Situations I, IV, and V) happen in this case, and the corresponding departure rates of the three situations are , , and , respectively. We can observe from Figure 2(a) that commuters departing before experience schedule delay early and always experience queuing; they will pass the bottleneck before the bottleneck capacity drops. Thereafter, the queue length increased to when , and capacity drop happens when . Commuters during () experience schedule delay late and always experience queuing, and commuters departing after experience schedule delay late and possibly experience queuing.

Case 2 in Figure 2(b). Two situations (i.e., Situations I and IV) happen in this case, and the corresponding departure rates of the three situations are and . We can observe from Figure 2(b) that commuters departing before experience schedule delay early and always experience queuing; the queue length initially increases when , but the queue length ; then the queue length decreases when , so the capacity drop will not be triggered, and the bottleneck model follows the deterministic model. Commuters during () experience schedule delay late and always experience queuing.

Meanwhile in case 1, by definition, we haveand

Since the departure rates in the case have not changed, according the derivation process of , (29) still holds; substituting (48) and (49) into (29), we have

If , the commuting behaviors could be investigated analytically in the five situations; if , no commuters experience schedule delay early and pass the bottleneck after capacity drops.

The critical time points in Case 1 are given as follows:

Case 2 and the basic deterministic bottleneck model have the same set of formulae for time instants and . Let in Case 2 be the departure time for which an individual arrives at work on time. Then

Theorem 8. The maximum critical queue length which can trigger capacity drop is bigger than the longest queue in the basic deterministic bottleneck model; i.e., .

Proof. According to (8) and (50), we have the following.According to (44), we have . Because , it is easy to conclude . Therefore, the right-hand side of (56) is more than 0, so, holds.

Theorem 8 presents an interesting result. That is, if commuters believe the capacity drop will happen in the bottleneck, they will leave home earlier to avoid potential losses due to capacity drop, even if one may face a queue longer than the longest queue with the capacity drop. And in fact the capacity drop with critical queue length should never happen.

Next, we study the expected trip cost varying with the traffic demand over three distinct possible equilibrium patterns.

According to (50), for a given critical queue length , the capacity drop is activated over some time interval when , where

The three distinct possible equilibrium patterns, i.e., Case 2, Case 1, and the basic Case depicted in Figure 1, arise from successively larger values of . Thus the demand-varying expected trip cost can be formulated as a piecewise function.

It is straightforward to verify that the expected trip cost function is upper semicontinuous at .

Similar with the work by Fosgerau and Small [20], we present the marginal cost to understand the relationship between system performance and congestion.

The marginal cost is the derivative of total cost with respect to . Thus, we have the following.

Using the parameters presented in Table 1, the expected trip cost and marginal cost are given in Figure 3. The figure shows that the expected trip cost and marginal cost increase nonlinearly; both are discontinuous at . Hence, when heavy congestion exists, the congestion is more sensitive to travel demand. In addition, the larger capacity uncertainty (i.e., lessening the value of the parameter ) will further increase the sensitivity.

2.6. Comparison with Related Works

As Vickrey [7] developed a bottleneck model to capture the dynamics of traffic congestion, at equilibrium state, all commuters experience the same travel cost no matter when they leave home. Fosgerau and Small [20] analyzed an apparently complex system similarly to a bottleneck whose capacity declines when the queue is long enough. Xiao et al. [6] assumed the bottleneck capacity follows a uniform distribution and investigated the equilibrium associated with the stochastic bottleneck. The stochasticity of capacity variation combined is investigated in the watershed bottleneck model proposed in this paper, there are two stages with different capacity. The first stage follows the schedule delay early part of the deterministic bottleneck model, but the bottleneck capacity will drop in the second state into a stochastic amount when the queue at the bottleneck reaches a certain level. Therefore, travelers passing through the bottleneck with a high capacity need to leave home earlier, and under the influence of capacity drop and stochastic capacity, travelers departing at the same time of a day may arrive at their destination either early or late, but the commuters’ mean trip cost is constant with respect to a time instant.

From the theoretical aspects, Theorems 1, 2, and 4 in this paper are coincident with Theorems 1 and 2 and Proposition 3 in Xiao et al. [6]. Different from Xiao et al. [6], the departure rates in Situations III and V are dependent on the critical queue length and the occurrence time of capacity drop. In addition, the critical queue length will affect the equilibrium traffic flow pattern; this paper distinguishes two cases of equilibria associated with the capacity drop and derived the boundary conditions for all cases. We found that shrinking the length of the first stage will result in an increase in the length of peak period; when the critical queue length is set as , only Situations I, IV, and V will happen in the bottleneck, and , which means the capacity drop that should not happen also happened.

The three distinct possible equilibrium patterns could emerge with successively larger travel demand. Under the hypercongestion circumstances, the capacity drops and the expected trip cost and marginal cost increase with travel demand. The conclusion coincides with the results for a bottleneck with variable capacity investigated by Fosgerau and Small [20]. Moreover, it is found that the stochasticity of capacity variation will lead to the discontinuity of expected trip cost. In addition, larger capacity stochasticity could further increase the marginal cost with a higher speed with the travel demand, which means higher stochasticity could make the marginal cost more sensitive with travel demand variation.

From the above theorems, one could expect shorter congestion time period if the dispersion of capacity drop is relatively low. Therefore, it is reasonable to consider that control strategies aimed at traffic flow regularity could enhance the efficiency of the commuting systems from the congestion duration time point of view.

3. Time-Varying Toll and Step Toll Schemes

The capacity drop extends the morning peak and leads to loss of efficiency; hence it is meaningful to find approaches to alleviate the negative effects of capacity drop. From the theorems given in the previous section on bottleneck capacity drop, approaches to shortening the queue length could be expected to avoid the capacity drop. As the time-varying toll scheme could completely eliminate queue at bottleneck and therefore could avoid the capacity drop, in this section we design a time-varying toll scheme to enhance the efficiency of bottleneck. In addition, because of the difficulty for using the time-varying toll scheme in real world commuting system, we also propose a step toll scheme to achieve higher performance more practically.

3.1. Time-Varying Toll Scheme

The time-varying toll was designed as the first-best toll by Arnott et al. [29] in the general bottleneck model; they showed that the toll scheme could eliminate queue completely without raising schedule delay. Similarly, in this paper, we present the toll pricing which is designed to match the marginal travel time cost in the no-toll equilibrium:where and are given by (6) and is given by (7).

Since the queue could be eliminated completely under the time-varying toll scheme, the total cost of a trip and the peak period are the same as in the no-toll equilibrium. Noticing that the capacity drop studied in this paper associated with the bottleneck will not be triggered under the time-varying toll scheme, then the equilibrium flow pattern is the same as the case if capacity drop phenomenon is not considered.

Although the resulting departure and arrival patterns are identical for all sizes of travel demand, the performance for deploying the policy for the different travel demand is different. Firstly, relative to the congestion equilibrium with capacity drop, the bottleneck capacity could keep at the highest level under this toll scheme, which could decrease the commuters’ mean travel cost and shorten the peak period. Secondly, all queuing costs are eliminated under the toll scheme, and the travel cost for each commuter is . Combining both of the two cost saving parts, the total saving cost could be formulated as the difference between expected trip cost (ec) with and without time-varying toll as follows.

It is not difficult to verify that the total cost saving increases with travel demand . Essentially, under condition , the commuters’ difference between expected cost with and without time-varying toll is zero because the cost saving parts could be covered by the toll.

3.2. Step Toll Scheme

Since the time-varying toll is difficult to implement and hard to be accepted for government and commuters, now we try to find a more practical toll scheme, which is step toll scheme. This type of toll scheme could limit the queue length in a range to avoid capacity drop with finite number of steps.

As reviewed above, there are mainly three types of step toll scheme including ADL model, Laih model, and braking model [30]. In this paper, we design a step toll scheme based on Laih model to avoid the capacity drop, and we also try to find least number of steps that should be used to achieve optimal efficiency.

Firstly, we introduce some notations about the step toll scheme used in Laih model. It is assumed that there are levels of toll pricing in the schedule; the tolling period spans a time interval with a toll level , . The tolling periods are indexed and period is the central period containing . For clarity, a diagrammatic sketch for a 4-step toll scheme is illustrated in Figure 4. As is presented, the lower-charge interval is disconnected during the higher-charge interval ; optimal toll levels for the Laih model are

The optimal tolling periods for the Laih model are

To have a deeper insight of the equilibrium under the proposed step toll scheme, we discuss the queue length evolution process in equilibrium.

Case 1 (before tolling period 1). Under the proposed multistep toll scheme, the length of queue is at the moment when the toll is applied and also immediately before it is lifted. For commuters arriving early within [], the one arriving just before must experience a queuing time , which is longer than the queuing time the commuter arriving after may face and pay the toll . Therefore, the longest queue length during time interval [] is , which could be simplified aswhere denotes the longest queue length during time interval [] and is the longest queue under the equilibrium in the original setting without capacity drop.

Case 2 (during tolling period 1). The departure rate at equilibrium is for commuters who arrive early and is for commuters who arrive late, which is also the same as the rates in the no-toll equilibrium. The optimal multistep toll could be set so that the queue reaches 0 at , the total number of departures in [] is , and the longest queue length in [] is, therefore,

Case 3 (after tolling period 1). As in the Laih model, it is assumed that commuters who arrive just after may wait on a set of secondary lanes without impeding other commuters who arrive before and use the main set of lanes; there are separate queues which will dissipate at . To achieve the equilibrium, the commuter arriving just after must experience a waiting time that equals , which is equivalent to the case in which the commuter faces a queue with length . However, as illustrated in Figure 5, the longest queue at the secondary lanes is

In summary, the longest queue length under the -step toll scheme should be . Thus, if we letwhere denotes the ceil operator, then the longest queue length is

It is straightforward to conclude that the -step toll scheme can guarantee that the commuters face a queue length less than the critical length and capacity drop does not arise; on the other hand, the -step toll scheme with least number of steps is convenient for practical application.

Similar to the time-varying toll, the -step toll could avoid the capacity drop phenomenon and further shorten the queue length at bottleneck. The average cost with the -step toll for each commuter is ; then the total cost saving for each commuter could be formulated as follows.

From (69), it could also be concluded that the step toll asymptotically approaches the efficiency of the first-best toll as .

4. Numerical Examples

In this section, numerical results are presented for the bottleneck model without toll, with a time-varying toll, and with a multistep toll. As in Arnott et al. (1990b) and Xiao et al. [33], we first use , , and and consider the situation with , , , and , To ensure that all five situations could appear in no-toll equilibrium, the watershed number must be smaller than ; thus we consider , and the corresponding critical queue length that activates the capacity drop is

4.1. No-Toll Equilibrium in the Bottleneck

To obtain the departure rates in Situation III and V, we solve the differential equations (20) and (26) using the Euler method with step size equal to 0.005. Figure 6 shows the cumulative departure flows in the bottleneck. The rush hour starts at -1.12 and ends at 0.26. Note that separates the two stages mentioned above, but it is irrelevant to these watershed times that separate the five situations, and it is not always before .

The mean total travel cost, mean travel time cost, and the mean schedule delay and early costs are shown in Figure 7; at equilibrium, the mean total travel costs of all commuters are the same and equal to 4.35; the travel time cost reaches the highest point at time instant around -0.69, but the time point is neither at the one with the minimum of schedule delay early/late cost nor at the intersection of the schedule delay early cost curves and the schedule delay late cost curves. As expected, the queue exists and the travel time cost is nonzero at the end of the peak period. Interestingly, although the capacity of bottleneck will turn from deterministic to stochastic as it drops, the mean travel time costs are still linearly increasing or decreasing with departure time.

To understand the impact of stochasticity of the bottleneck capacity, Table 2 reports the sensitivity analysis results for different values of and . We change the -value from 0.75 to 1.0 when , and from 500 to 2500 when , respectively; it is shown that both the length of peak period and the mean trip cost increase as the -value decreases, which is consistent with Theorem 4. Because smaller -value will bring more uncertainty, then commuters will depart earlier to avoid potential losses, which will also increase the total travel cost of the whole system. As many works use the concept reliability to capture the stochasticity of the transportation systems [37], higher level of stochasticity may lead to more unreliability and make the systems less efficient consequently. In addition, from the table, we can also find that when , time points and . It means that the elimination of the stochasticity of bottleneck model degrade into the deterministic model. By contrast, both the length of peak period and the mean trip cost decrease as the increases, which is consistent with Theorem 4. Since increasing the critical queue length is equivalent to prolonging the period of the first stage of the bottleneck, commuters departing at the same time could enjoy higher capacity than the one in the model with shorter critical queue length.

Figure 8 depicts the departure rates for different -values. It shows that in equilibrium the departure rate is monotonically decreasing with time, and the departure rate is around zero at the end of the peak period. Moreover, under the influence of the capacity drop of bottleneck, the departure rate suffers “a cliff-like drop” too, and when the -value approaches one, the stochastic bottleneck model follows the deterministic model.

4.2. Time-Varying Toll in the Bottleneck Model

For equilibrium under time-varying toll scheme, the results are given in Table 3 and are identical to the case without capacity drop as discussed in Section 2.

4.3. Step Toll in the Bottleneck Model

With the input data of , , , , , the longest queue in bottleneck model when capacity drop is not considered is . To avoid the capacity drop, the number of steps in the toll schedule needs to satisfy ; i.e., a single-step toll can avoid the capacity drop under this condition.

Despite the practicability which step toll schemes may have, the loss of efficiency should also be considered. In the following, we compare the performance of the bottleneck with single-step toll and the time-varying toll in Table 3. Specifically, the notations TC, TTC, and SDC denote total travel cost, total travel time cost, and total schedule delay cost, respectively.

From Table 4, one could see that in terms of the total travel time cost, the single-step toll is not so effective compared to time-varying toll. Compared with classical Vickrey model, the single-step toll could eliminate half of the total queuing time that exists in the no-toll equilibrium when capacity drop does not happen.

As multistep toll scheme can avoid capacity drop with the least number of steps, Figure 9 shows the least number of steps of multistep toll scheme for different values. From the figure, one can see that value could affect the least number of steps. Furthermore, as the value increases, the decrement speed of the least number of steps becomes slow.

5. Conclusions

In this paper, we analyze the impacts of capacity drop on commuting systems using a bottleneck model. Following the empirical findings by Lorenz and Elefteriadou [4] and Brilon et al. [5], it is assumed that the bottleneck capacity could drop stochastically because of the irregularity of traffic flow. Under the assumption that the commuters’ departure time choice follows UE principle in terms of mean travel cost, analytical solutions have been derived in five situations. Several properties of the proposed bottleneck model with stochastic capacity drop are discussed, including monotonicity of travel cost and departure rate, and the relationship between dispersion degree and length of peak period. In addition, the other two possible departure patterns associated with the capacity drop are given.

Furthermore, two types of toll pricing schemes are also proposed to avoid the capacity drop, including time-varying toll scheme and step toll scheme. Specifically, the time-varying toll could eliminate the queue completely. The resulting equilibrium flow pattern is the same as that when capacity drop could not happen. To seek more practical approaches to enhance the efficiency of the commuting system, step toll pricing scheme is proposed and discussed. For any given critical queue length, multistep toll with least number of steps could be designed to achieve the optimal efficiency of the bottleneck under the step toll schemes.

In addition, numerical results are also presented to demonstrate the impact of capacity drop. It is shown that the capacity drop phenomenon would increase the mean travel cost, and it is helpful to reduce the critical queue length to enhance the efficiency of the system by using approaches for regulating the traffic flow.

Appendix

A. Notations

: Number of commuters: Bottleneck capacity: Free flow travel time: Preferred arrival time: Earliest departure time: Departure time at which an individual arrives at the CBD on time : Ending time of the rush hour: Departure rate: Cumulative departures: Queue length at time : Queuing time at time : Total cost at time : Travel cost at equilibrium: Values of travel time: Values of schedule delay early: Values of schedule delay late: Longest queue length at equilibrium: Critical point of queue length for capacity drop: Full capacity of the bottleneck: Upper bound of the dropped capacity: Parameter to characterizing the capacity drop, as : Parameter to characterizing the lower bound of dropped capacity: The time point at which the queue length reaches : The time point at which the capacity drops: The time point at which separate commuters “always arrive early” and “can arrive early or late”: The time point at which separate commuters “arrive early or late” and “always arrive late and incur a queuing delay”: The time point at which separate commuters “always arrive late and incur a queuing delay” and “always arrive late and, depending on capacity, may or may not incur a queuing delay”: Earliest departure time in case 1: The time point in case 1 at which the queue length reaches : The time point in case 1 at which separate commuters “always arrive late and incur a queuing delay” and “always arrive late and, depending on capacity, may or may not incur a queuing delay”: Ending time of the rush hour in case 1: The departure time in case 2 for which an individual arrives at work on time: Cumulative number of departures by time : Toll pricing matches the marginal cost: Numbers of toll levels: Start time point of the tolling period at level : End time point of the tolling period at level : Toll at level : Least number of step toll levels: Longest queue length with least number of step toll levels.

Data Availability

All relevant data used to support the findings of this study are included within the article.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare that they have no conflicts of interest.

Acknowledgments

This work is jointly supported by the National Natural Science Foundation of China (Grant No. 71371028, 71621001) and Beijing Natural Science Foundation (Grant No. 9172013).