Abstract

We give an alternative duality-based proof to the solution of the expected utility maximization problem analyzed by Kim and Omberg. In so doing, we also provide an example of incomplete-market optimal investment problem for which the duality approach is conducive to an explicit solution.

1. Introduction

Kim and Omberg [1] study a problem of utility maximization from terminal wealth in a continuous-time market, allowing the Sharpe ratio of the risky asset to follow a mean-reverting process. As in the seminal paper [2], they address the problem using a stochastic control approach, despite the lack of a verification theorem supporting the uniqueness of their results. We provide a rigorous solution to Kim and Omberg’s problem by using a probabilistic approach based on convex duality. Since the market is not complete, we refer to the very general results by Kramkov and Schachermayer [3, 4]. Other references on convex duality methods both in the complete and in the incomplete case can be found in [59]. Haugh et al. [6] exploit the dual formulation of the optimal portfolio problem to determine an upper bound on the unknown maximum expected utility in order to evaluate the quality of approximation of the optimal solution. As they observe, explicit solutions are rare in incomplete markets where the opportunity set is stochastic. We thus add to the literature by providing an example where the duality approach succeeds in characterizing explicitly the value function, the optimal solutions to both the primal and the dual problem, and the optimal strategy.

In Section 2, we describe the basic market model of Kim and Omberg. In Section 3, we apply the duality approach to the solution of the utility maximization problem from terminal wealth and find the optimal solutions to both the primal and the dual problems. Finally, in Section 4, we recover Kim and Omberg’s results, characterizing the optimal value function and the optimal strategy.

2. The Market

The investor trades two assets, a risk-free asset and a risky asset in a frictionless continuous-time market, modeled through a stochastic basis satisfying the usual assumptions (in the sense of Definitions I.1.2 and I.1.3 in [10]). The price of the risky asset follows the dynamicswhere is a standard Brownian motion and and are diffusion processes. The risk premium on the risky asset follows a mean-reverting Ornstein-Uhlenbeck process. The coefficients and are assumed to be sufficiently regular so that there exists a unique solution to the stochastic differential equation defining . This is the case, e.g., when is constant (and, consequently, ). A list of sufficient conditions on the coefficients for the existence and uniqueness of the solution of the stochastic differential equation can be found in Section 1.2 of [11]. Weaker conditions can be found in [12] (see also the references therein). The dynamics of iswhere , , and are positive constants and is a Brownian motion correlated with , with and . We can assume, without loss of generality, that is the filtration generated by and .

Let be the value process of a self-financing portfolio, given the initial wealth . The discounted value process is given bywhere and is an adapted process representing the amount of shares of risky asset in the portfolio. We call the strategy admissible if there exists some constant such that almost surely, and, to rule out strategies generating arbitrage profit, we allow only for admissible strategies. In accordance with Kim and Omberg [1], we express the wealth in terms of the monetary investment in the risky asset ; that is,

3. Utility Maximization with the Duality Approach

We consider the problem of an agent whose aim is to maximize his/her expected utility from terminal wealth. The investor has a HARA utility function, of the formfor , , . We collect in the set all the nonnegative self-financing portfolios with initial value and denote by the set of the corresponding discounted portfolios, namely,The problem of utility maximization from terminal wealth can be written as where we defineTo find the function , we apply the duality approach developed in [3, 4]. For convenience of the reader, we recall the results due to Kramkov and Schachermayer (in particular, [4, Theorems and ]) which will be exploited henceforth.

Let denote the conjugate function of (the functions and are conjugate if and only if and ); that is, . We define the set and consider the following optimization problem:Let . is an equivalent local martingale and defineUnder the assumption that the set of equivalent local martingale measures is nonempty and that satisfies Inada conditions ((2.4) in [3] or in [4]), we have that if for all (see Note 3 in [4]), then(1) for all ; there exists some such that for , and and are conjugate;(2)the optimal solution to (8) exists and is unique. If is the optimal solution to (10), with (or equivalently ), we have the dual relation , where ;(3).

When , the market is complete and the martingale measure is unique; therefore the set is a singleton (provided that it is nonempty). In this case, the above results reduce to Theorem 2.0 in [3]. The complete case can be outlined following [13], where a similar analysis is carried on, under the assumption that the price process follows CEV dynamics. In the present paper, we limit our analysis to the more complex case   , where the set of local equivalent martingale measures has infinitely many elements, among which we look for the optimal solution of the dual problem. Observe that the utility function defined as (5) satisfies Inada conditions. So we only need to prove that the set of equivalent martingale measures is nonempty, in order to apply the duality approach. This is done in the next lemma.

Lemma 1. The set is not empty.

Proof. It is sufficient to prove that there exists at least an equivalent local martingale measure. Let where we denote by the stochastic exponential; see, e.g., [10, section  II.8a.]. The random variable is the Radon-Nikodym density of an equivalent local martingale measure, provided that (see [14]). There are several ways to show this result. One can, e.g., prove Novikov’s condition on sufficiently small intervals and exploit Corollary 3.5.14 in [15] or one can follow an argument similar to that used in [16], recalling that an Ornstein-Uhlenbeck process satisfies almost surely. We choose to exploit the relation between the martingale property and the solution of stochastic differential equations and, in particular, the recent results in [17] that in turn extend the method of [18] (an alternative approach has been recently developed in [19]).
We first introduce the processwhich is a Brownian motion independent of . Note that the filtration coincides with the filtration generated by and Using the same notation as in [17], we set :It follows that , , and
Then, one can find such thatand the assumptions of Theorem 8.1 in [17] are satisfied. As a consequence .

To solve explicitly our problem, we proceed as follows. We first assume that there exists an optimal solution for the dual problem (10). From , we derive the solution of the primal problem , and, exploiting the fact that it must be the final value of a self-financing portfolio, we are able to explicitly characterize the candidate solutions and . Finally, we show that the characterized is really the density of an equivalent martingale measure and the optimal solution of problem (10), namely, that our initial assumption is satisfied and is the maximal expected utility given the initial wealth .

As announced before, we make the following assumption, which will be proved to be true in Lemma 4.

Assumption 1. There exists such that .

Our first results characterize both solutions of the primal and the dual problem, given that they exist.

Lemma 2. Under Assumption 1, the optimal solution to (8) exists and is given by

Proof. From the condition , we get . HenceThe claim is then proved.

The discounted optimal wealth (15) is the final value of a self-financing discounted portfolio, which, under the optimal martingale measure . , admits the representationwhere is a -Brownian motion. We denote and . Recalling that and the expression for in (15) we obtain thatDenotewhere is defined in (12), and let be the set of processes such that is a Radon-Nikodym density. The set is nonempty since it contains . Every equivalent local martingale measure has a Radon-Nikodym density of the form , with . Assumption 1 guarantees that there exists such that . ThenTo find the stochastic differential of , we denote where and satisfies the stochastic differential equation (2). Thenprovided that the process on the right-hand side is a martingale. Letting (so that ) and denoting by , , and , respectively, the first partial derivatives of with respect to , , and the second partial derivative of with respect to , Ito’s formula yields (for sake of notation, we omit the dependence of , , and on )Applying again Ito’s formula to and recalling that is a -martingale (hence the drift part in its Ito decomposition is null), we findwhere and are independent Brownian motions. The process coincides with the value of a self-financing discounted portfolio (note that, in this case, the process is an exponential martingale under , and hence it is strictly positive, namely, ) if and only if it has form (17), namely, or, equivalently,

Lemma 3. The function is given bywhere , , and are the solutions of the differential equationswith the initial conditions , and provided that belongs to , which is the largest interval on which (28) admits bounded solutions.

Proof. We exploit the fact that the process defined in (22) is a martingale, and hence the drift part in its Ito decomposition must be 0; that is,Since the above equation must hold when applied at any pair with , the martingale condition amounts to require that satisfies the following partial differential equation: for all , and for all If we guess a solution of the formwe obtain the partial differential equations (28) for , , and with the initial conditions , , and .

We show now that is the density of an equivalent local martingale measure and the optimal solution of the dual problem (10).

Lemma 4. (1) and hence .
(2) The density is the optimal solution to problem (10), and, as a consequence,

Proof. (1) We can follow the same argument as in the proof of Lemma 1 and apply the results in [17], recalling that and defined in (28) are bounded on when (see Appendix in [1]).
(2) We already know that the density of every equivalent martingale measure has the form with . Let , and observe that . Denote Thenwith . Thenwhere is the expectation with respect to the probability measure . . Note that the process is a -Brownian motion and Since the function is convex, Jensen’s inequality yields where the last equality comes from being a -Brownian motion and . The equality holds, and the infimum is attained, when , that is, . This shows that the density is the optimal solution to the dual problem (10).

4. Value Function and Optimal Strategy

We exploit the results of the previous section to obtain the explicit expressions of the value function and of the optimal strategy, depending on the current wealth level , the current Sharpe ratio , and the time to maturity . Of course, our results coincide with Kim and Omberg’s results ([1, formulas (16)–(21)]).

Theorem 5. (1) The maximum expected utility iswhere , , and .
(2) The optimal monetary investment in the risky asset is

Proof. (1) We replace the optimal wealth (15) in (8). The value function is then (2) Comparing (17) and (24), , we obtainReplacing , the claim is proved.

Remark 6. In our results we worked out the solution of the problem of utility maximization from terminal wealth starting at the initial date . The analysis extends to any date by replacing unconditional expectations with time -conditional expectations, the initial investment horizon with the current investment horizon , and the initial values of and with the current ones.

5. Conclusions

We work out a duality-based proof to the solution of the optimal incomplete-market portfolio problem studied by Kim and Omberg [1]. Our analysis offers an example where the duality approach succeeds in finding explicit results.

Conflict of Interests

The authors declare that there is no conflict of interests regarding the publication of this paper.