Abstract

This paper concerns the recursive utility maximization problem for terminal wealth under partial information. We first transform our problem under partial information into the one under full information. When the generator of the recursive utility is concave, we adopt the variational formulation of the recursive utility which leads to a stochastic game problem and characterization of the saddle point of the game is obtained. Then, we study the -ignorance case and explicit saddle points of several examples are obtained. At last, when the generator of the recursive utility is smooth, we employ the terminal perturbation method to characterize the optimal terminal wealth.

1. Introduction

In this paper, we study the problem of an agent who invests in a financial market so as to maximize the recursive utility of his terminal wealth on finite time interval , while the recursive utility is characterized by the initial value of the following Backward stochastic differential equation (BSDE for short)The market consists of a riskless asset and risky assets, the latter being driven by a -dimensional Brownian motion. And the investor has access only to the history of interest rates and prices of risky assets, while the appreciation rate and the driving Brownian motion are not directly observed. That is, the filtration generated by the Brownian motion could not be used when the investor chooses his portfolios. This is quite practical in a real financial market. So we are interested in this so-called recursive utility maximization problem under partial information.

In the full information case, the problem of maximizing the expected utility of terminal wealth is well understood in a complete or constrained financial market [1, 2]. In an incomplete multiple-priors model, Quenez [3] studied the problem of maximization of utility of terminal wealth in which the asset prices are semimartingales. Schied [4] studied the robust utility maximization problem in a complete market under the existence of a “least favorable measure.” As for the recursive utility optimization, El Karoui et al. [5] studied the optimization of recursive utilities when the generator of BSDE is smooth. Epstein and Ji [6, 7] formulated a model of recursive utility that captures the decision-maker’s concern with ambiguity about both the drift and ambiguity and studied the recursive utility optimization under -framework. Hu et al. [8] introduced a BSDE driven by -Brownian motion from which a kind of more general recursive utility can be defined. Then Hu and Ji [9, 10] studied the corresponding control problem by two methods: maximum principle and dynamic programming principle. But all the above works do not accommodate partial information.

In the partial information case, Lakner [11] generalized the martingale method to expected utility maximization problem; see also Pham [12]. Cvitanić et al. [13] maximized the recursive utility under partial information. But the generator in Cvitanić et al. [13] does not depend on . Miao [14] studied a special case of recursive multiple-priors utility maximization problem under partial information in which the appreciation rate is assumed to be an -measurable, unobserved random variable with known distribution. Actually, they studied the problem under Bayesian framework and did not give the explicit solutions.

In this paper, we first transform our portfolio selection problem under partial information into one under full information in which the unknown appreciation rate is replaced by its filter estimate and the Brownian motion is replaced by the innovation process. Then a backward formulation of the problem under full information is built in which instead of the portfolio process, the terminal wealth is regarded as the control variable. This backward formulation is based on the existence and uniqueness theorem of BSDE and was introduced in [5, 15].

When the generator of (1) is concave, we adopt the variational formulation of the recursive utility which leads to a stochastic game problem. Inspired by the convexity duality method developed in Cvitanić and Karatzas [16], we turn the primal “sup-inf” problem to a dual minimization problem over a set of discounting factors and equivalent probability measures. A characterization of the saddle point of this game is obtained in this paper. Furthermore, the explicit saddle points for several classical examples are worked out.

When the generator of the BSDE is smooth, we apply the terminal perturbation method developed in Ji and Zhou [17] and Ji and Peng [18] to characterize the optimal terminal wealth of the investor. Once the optimal terminal wealth is obtained, the determination of the optimal portfolio process is a martingale representation problem which we do not involve in this paper.

The rest of this paper is organized as follows. In Section 2, we formulate the recursive utility maximization problem under partial information, reduce the original problem to a problem under full information, and give the backward formulation. The case of nonsmooth generator is tackled in Section 3. In Section 4, we specialize in -ignorance model and give explicit saddle points of several examples. In Section 5, we characterize the optimal wealth when the generator is smooth.

2. The Problem of Recursive Utility Maximization under Partial Observation

2.1. Classical Formulation of the Problem

We consider a financial market consisting of a riskless asset whose price process is assumed for simplicity to be equal to one and risky securities (the stocks) whose prices are stochastic processes , governed by the following SDEs:where is a standard -dimensional Brownian motion defined on a filtered complete probability space . is the appreciation rate of the stocks which is -adapted, bounded, and the matrix is the disperse rate of the stocks. Here and throughout the paper denotes the transpose operator.

The asset prices are assumed to be continuously observed by the investors in this market; in other words, the information available to the investors is represented by , which is the -augmentation of the filtration generated by the price processes . The matrix disperse coefficient is assumed invertible, bounded uniformly, and , , , , a.s. In fact, can be obtained from the quadratic variation of the price process. So we assume w.l.o.g. that is -adapted. However, the appreciation rate is not observable for the investors.

A small investor whose actions cannot affect the market prices can decide at time what amount of his wealth to invest in the th stock, . Of course, his decision can only be based on the available information ; that is, the processes are progressively measurable and satisfy

Then the wealth process of a self-financing investor who is endowed with initial wealth satisfies the following stochastic differential equation:

Because the only information available to the investor is , we could not use the Brownian motion to define the recursive utility. As we will show in the following, there exists a Brownian motion under in the filtered measurable space which is often referred to as an innovation process. The recursive utility process of the investor is defined by the following backward stochastic differential equation:where and are functions satisfying the following assumptions.

Assumption 1. (A1) is -progressively measurable for any .
(A2) There exists a constant such that(A3) is continuous about and

Assumption 2. is continuously differentiable and satisfies linear growth condition.

Remark 3. Equation (4) is not a standard BSDE because in general is strictly larger than the augmented filtration of the -Brownian motion .

We introduce the following spaces:

For notational simplicity, we will often write , and instead of , , and , respectively.

We will show in the next subsection that under Assumption 1, for any , the BSDE (4) has a unique solution . Then for each , and Assumption 2 ensures that the variable . Thus, under Assumptions 1 and 2, the recursive utility process associated with this terminal value is well defined.

Given an utility function satisfying Assumption 2 and initial endowment , the recursive utility maximization problem with bankruptcy prohibition is formulated as the investor chooses a portfolio strategy so as towhere means that no-bankruptcy is required.

Definition 4. A portfolio is said to be admissible if and the corresponding wealth processes , , a.s.

Given initial wealth , denote by the set of investor’s feasible portfolio strategies; that is

2.2. Reduction to a Problem under Full Information

Define the risk premium process . Because we have assumed the processes and are uniformly bounded, the processis a martingale. So a probability measure can be defined by is usually called risk neutral probability in the financial market. The processis a Brownian motion under by Girsanov’s theorem.

Then we can rewrite the stock price processes (2) as

Note that is assumed to be bounded, invertible, and -adapted. So the filtration coincides with the augmented natural filtration of by Theorem V. in [19].

Let be a measurable version of the conditional expectation of with respect to the filtration . Set : . Then , since is -adapted.

We introduce the process

By Theorem and Remark in Kallianpur [20], is a -Brownian motion which is the so-called innovations process. Then, we could describe the dynamics of stock price processes and the wealth process within a full observation model:

Now all the coefficients in our model are observable. So we are in a full observation model and our problem (7) can be reformulated as follows:

2.3. Backward Formulation of the Problem

In this subsection, we first show BSDE (4) has a unique solution under some mild conditions and then give an equivalent backward formulation of problem (15).

Lemma 5. Under Assumption 1, for , there exists a unique solution to the BSDE (4).

Since is strictly larger than the augmented filtration of the -Brownian motion in general, equation (4) is not a standard BSDE. Fortunately, by Theorem in [20], every square integrable -martingale can be represented aswhere . Thus, applying similar analysis as in [21], it is easy to prove this lemma.

Let . Since is invertible, can be regarded as the control variable instead of . By the existence and uniqueness result of BSDE (4), selecting is equivalent to selecting the terminal wealth . If we take the terminal wealth as control variable, the wealth equation and recursive utility process can be written aswhere the “control” is the terminal wealth to be chosen from the following set:

From now on, we denote the solution of (17) by . We also denote and by and , respectively.

As implied by the comparison theorem for BSDE (4), the nonnegative terminal wealth () keeps the wealth process nonnegative all the time. This gives rise to the following optimization problem:

Definition 6. A random variable is called feasible for the initial wealth if and only if . We will denote the set of all feasible for the initial wealth by .

It is clear that original problems (7) and (15) are equivalent to the auxiliary one (19). Hence, hereafter we focus ourselves on solving (19). Note that becomes the control variable. The advantage of this approach is that the state constraint in (7) becomes a control constraint in (19), whereas it is well known in control theory that a control constraint is much easier to deal with than a state constraint. The cost of this approach is the original initial condition that now becomes a constraint.

Feasible is called optimal if it attains the maximum of over . Once is determined, the optimal portfolio can be obtained by solving the first equation in (17) with .

3. Dual Method for Recursive Utility Maximization

In this section, we impose the following concavity condition.

Assumption 7. The function is concave for all .

We also need the following assumption on .

Assumption 8. is strictly increasing, strictly concave, and continuously differentiable, and satisfies

Under Assumption 8, Assumption 2 seems too restrictive and it precludes some interesting examples. So in the following two sections, for any given utility function satisfying Assumption 8, we set

In this section, we assume , the -dimensional identity matrix. Let be the Fenchel-Legendre transform of :Let the effective domain of be . As was shown in [22], the -section of , denoted by is included in the bounded domain , where is the Lipschitz constant of .

We have the duality relation by the concavity of ,For every the infimum is achieved in this relation by a pair which depends on .

SetThen is a convex set. For any , letand denote by the unique solution to the linear BSDE (4) with .

By similar analysis as Proposition in [22], we have the following variational formulation of and .

Lemma 9. Under Assumptions 1 and 7, for any , the solutions of (17) can be represented as where In particular, we have .

Remark 10. By Theorem in [11], we have , , a.s.

By Lemma 9, . Thus, our problem is equivalent to the following problem:

The maximum recursive utility that the investor can achieve isIt is dominated by its “min-max” counterpart

If we can find such thatthen the optimal solution of problem (28) is .

Let us introduce the monotone decreasing function as the inverse of the marginal utility function and the convex dual

Then, , , ,

Furthermore, we have equality in the above formula for some , , if and only if the conditionsare satisfied simultaneously. And in this case, we have

Lemma 11. Under Assumptions 1, 7, anfd 8, suppose that there exists a quadruple which satisfies (34) andThen we have , , andThat is, is a saddle point satisfying (31).

Proof. We only prove the first relationship in (37). Let and in (33). We get by (35). This completes the proof.

Let us introduce the value functionBy (33), we havewhere

Lemma 12. Under the assumptions of Lemma 11, the followings hold:(i) attains the infimum in (39) with .(ii)The triple attains the first infimum in (41).(iii)The number attains the second infimum in (41).(iv)There is no “duality gap” in (40); that is,

Proof. (i) By (35) and (36), where the last inequality is due to (33).
(ii) By (35) and (36), we have where the last inequality is an application of (33) to .
(iii) By (i), (35), and (36), So we get , .
(iv) By (ii) and (35), This completes the proof.

In the following, we prove the existence of the quadruple which is postulated in Lemma 11.

Notice that the function is convex. By similar analysis as in Appendix of [23], the following lemma holds.

Lemma 13. Under Assumptions 1, 7, and 8, for any given , there exists a pair which attains the infimum in (39).

Lemma 14. Under Assumptions 1, 7, and 8, supposeThen for any given , there exists a number which attains

Proof.
Step 1. By the convexity of and Lemma 13, is convex. Fix ; denote as in Lemma 13. For any , we have Then, by Levi’s lemma,Since is convex, we obtain that is differentiable on and .
Step 2. Because is bounded, we have that, for any , , a.s. Then,Thus, there exists a number which attains and . This completes the proof.

Lemma 15. Under Assumptions 1, 7, and 8, with as in Lemma 14 and as in Lemma 13.

Proof. We have This completes the proof.

Our main result is the following theorem.

Theorem 16. Under Assumptions 1, 7, and 8, let as in Lemma 15 and define If , then satisfies all the conditions in Lemma 11, that is, (34) and (36).

Proof. Notice thatApplying the maximum principle in Peng [24], we obtain a necessary condition for :where is the solution of the adjoint equation; let and be the unique solutions of the following two linear BSDEs:By (53) and the comparison theorem of BSDE, we have , , a.s., especially
Solving the above linear BSDEs givesSowhich exactly is (36).
By Lemma 14, . By Lemma 13,Differentiating both sides of (59) as functions of , we getThis completes the proof.

Remark 17. It is worth pointing out that the adjoint process in the proof of the above theorem coincides with the optimal utility process in (55).

4. -Ignorance

In this section, we study a special case which is called -ignorance by Chen and Epstein [25]. In this case, the generator is specified asChen and Epstein interpreted the term as modeling ambiguity aversion rather than risk aversion. is not differentiable. But it is concave and . Then our results in the above section are still applicable.

In this section, we assume , . The wealth equation and recursive utility becomeOur problem is formulated as follows:

Now Lemma 9 can be simplified to the following lemma.

Lemma 18. For , the solutions and of (62) can be represented as where

For any , is -martingale. Then, a new probability measure is defined on byand is a Brownian motion under . Thus, where is the expectation operator with respect to .

Our problem (63) is equivalent to the following problem:The auxiliary dual problem in (39) becomeswhere , a.s. and

Applying the procedure in the previous section, we can find the saddle point. So we list the results without proof except Lemma 19 in which a new proof is given.

Lemma 19. Under Assumption 8, for any given , there exists a unique which attains the infimum in (68).

Proof. Set , , and for . Then problem (68) becomeswhere is the expectation operator with respect to the risk neutral measure . By Theorem in [25], we know is norm closed in . So is closed under a.s. convergence because is uniformly integrable. As a consequence, is closed under a.s. convergence.
Consider a minimizing sequence for (70); that isBy Komlos’ theorem, there exists a sequence conv; that is, , , and , such that the sequence converges a.s. to a random variable . By a.s. closedness of , we have ; that is, , s.t. . Note that is a strictly convex continuous function; we have The uniqueness follows from the strict convexity of . This completes the proof.

Lemma 20. Under Assumption 8, if , , , then for any given , there exists a number which attains the infimum of .

Lemma 21. Under Assumption 8, with as in Lemma 20 and as in Lemma 19.

Theorem 22. Under Assumption 8, let be the same as in Lemma 21; then the optimal terminal wealth of problem (67) isif belongs to .

In the following, we give some examples to illustrate our above analysis.

Example 23 (constant absolute risk aversion). Suppose that , , , and the wealth of the investor may be negative. This utility function does not satisfy Assumption 8. But it satisfies the following assumption.

Assumption 24. is strictly increasing, strictly concave, and continuously differentiable, andNote that under Assumption 24, the wealth process of the investor is allowed to be negative; the results in this section still hold.
For this example, , , and , . Then the value function of the auxiliary dual problem (68) is Apparently, (optimal ) which attains the infimum of Problem (68) is independent of . It is easy to see thatThe optimal value of problem (68) isand the Lagrange multiplier in Lemma 20 isThus, the optimal terminal wealth in Theorem 22 isMoreover, it is easy to check that and uniquely solves the utility equation in (62) when .
Note that and are bounded; it is easy to verify and .

Example 25 (logarithmic utility function). Suppose , In this case,Then the value function of the auxiliary dual problem (68) is So the optimal is independent of . Consider the following BSDE:Set It is easy to show that is uniformly Lipschitz, so the following BSDE has a unique solution which we still denoted by .Then the infimum in problem (68) is attained at The Lagrange multiplier in Lemma 20 isThe optimal terminal wealth in Theorem 22 isNote that and are bounded; it is easy to verify and .

Example 26. Suppose that the appreciation rate is a bounded deterministic function of . In this case, , , and we claim that

Proof. We show that defined above attains the infimum of (68). DenoteThen is the solution of the partial differential equation
; applying Itô’s formula to , we have By the definition of (88), we have , . The convexity of guarantees that is a submartingale. Thus, ,This completes the proof.

Example 27. Suppose that , a.e., a.s. Then we have Note that belongs to when , a.e. a.s. Due to the convexity of , we have that ,In this case, coincides with the risk neutral probability on which leads to the optimal terminal wealth . This means that the investor will not invest in the risk assets at all.

Remark 28. For recursive utility for consumption of the formwhere and satisfy Assumptions 2 and 8 and Assumptions 1 and 7, respectively, our method still works well.

5. Terminal Perturbation Method

When the generator of the recursive utility (4) is nonconcave, the dual method is not applicable. In this case, we apply the terminal perturbation method to obtain a characterization of the optimal terminal wealth. We need the following smooth assumption.

Assumption 29. is continuously differentiable in .

Let be an optimal terminal wealth for (19); that is,And let be the corresponding state processes of (17).

SetBy the terminal perturbation method in [17, 18], we have the following stochastic maximum principle.

Theorem 30. Under Assumptions 1, 2, and 29, if is the optimal wealth of problem (19), then there exist , , and such thatwhereand , .

Remark 31. Note that we do not need the concavity property of in the above theorem.

Competing Interests

The authors declare that there is no conflict of interests regarding the publication of this paper.

Acknowledgments

This work was supported by National Natural Science Foundation of China (no. 11571203) to Shaolin Ji. This work was supported by National Natural Science Foundation of China (no. 11401091) to Xiaomin Shi.