Abstract

This study aims to investigate the research and development (R&D) competition within the supply chain, focusing on two aspects: R&D competition at the manufacturing level and competition in pricing strategies. This paper establishes a dynamic game model of R&D competition, comprising two manufacturers and two retailers, with both manufacturers exhibiting bounded rationality. The key findings are as follows: (1) an increase in the adjustment speed positively affects the chaotic nature of the R&D competition system, leading to a state of disorder. This chaotic state has adverse implications for manufacturing profitability. (2) The spillover effect exhibits a positive relationship with the level of chaos in the R&D competition system. A greater spillover effect contributes to a more turbulent environment, which subsequently impacts the profitability of manufacturers. (3) R&D cost parameters exert a positive influence on the stability of the R&D competition system. When the system reaches a state of equilibrium, an escalation in the R&D cost parameters poses a threat to manufacturer profitability. (4) Retailer costs play a detrimental role in the stability of the R&D competition system. As retailer costs increase, there is a decline in R&D levels, thereby diminishing manufacturer profitability. (5) To mitigate the chaotic state, we propose the implementation of the time-delayed feedback control (TDFC) method, which reflects a more stable state in the R&D competition system.

1. Introduction

In the era of the knowledge economy and digitalization, businesses are increasingly emphasizing their technological innovation endeavors to adapt to external environmental changes and gain a competitive advantage. Numerous occurrences of cooperative innovation have manifested within various supply chains [1], as evidenced by partnerships between renowned automotive manufacturers GM and Benz with intermediaries from diverse nations. Likewise, in the context of China’s community-based vegetable procurement, collaborative endeavors between vegetable suppliers and retailers have led to significant business model innovations. Technological innovation plays a vital role in driving economic growth at both national and regional levels, as well as boosting company profits [2]. Consequently, competition among firms in research and development (R&D) has become more intense. R&D activities are instrumental in enhancing firms’ core competitiveness, reducing operational costs, and cultivating unique aspects of their business that provide an edge over competitors. However, engaging in R&D activities also presents decision-making challenges for firms [3], while the complexity associated with managing R&D activities leads to numerous management hurdles [4]. Moreover, the competitive nature of R&D strategies contributes to intricate behaviors within the entire system. In the real world, the spillover effect has emerged as a significant phenomenon in R&D activities, making it impossible for manufacturers to exclude competitors solely through their own R&D efforts.

As a consequence, the collaboration and R&D activities within the supply chain have led to an escalation of competitive dynamics [2]. In the event of competition failing, it precipitates detrimental implications for all involved entities within the supply chain. The losses incurred by enterprises such as Shi Hui Tuan and Ding Dong Maicai in 2021 substantially diminished the profits of vegetable suppliers and retailers, and in some cases, even resulted in their outright closure. Hence, given this scenario, it becomes imperative to address the ensuing questions concerning channel strategies: How do channels engage in competitive R&D? What are the ramifications of such competitive endeavors? How can the competitive behavior of channel partners be regulated?

The innovation of this article is comprised of the following facets: First, the present study presents an extension of the R&D competition model within the domain of the supply chain. By amalgamating R&D theory with the tenets of chaos theory, we systematically analyze the equilibrium points of the R&D competition system under the conditions of bounded rationality among participants, subsequently investigating the multifaceted dynamics that emerge in various scenarios. Second, we employ the time-delayed feedback control (TDFC) method as a strategic approach. By employing TDFC, our research endeavors to proficiently regulate chaotic phenomena. Our findings have revealed that TDFC not only diminishes the incidence of bifurcation and chaotic phenomena but also ensures the preservation of the original level of innovation, thereby safeguarding the efficacy of market mechanisms.

2. Literature Review

During the literature review, we have classified the papers into two distinct categories: the R&D stream that primarily focuses on investigating the spillover effects of research and development and the chaos theory stream that primarily focuses on the topics of bifurcation and chaos control.

The primary focus of the first stream lies in the realm of R&D within the supply chain. In this domain, corporations find themselves equipped with a competitive advantage through their ventures in R&D. The R&D activities of manufacturers exhibit a dual benefit, positively impacting both end-consumers and retailers [5]. Indeed, it is imperative to recognize that these R&D endeavors can give rise to the manifestation of diverse competitive strategies among enterprises [1]. In their insightful exploration of R&D collaboration within a supply chain, the authors of [6] assert that firms should diligently evaluate the spillover effect prior to embarking on cooperative R&D initiatives. Moreover, their research seeks to unravel the intricacies that underscore the occurrence of R&D-induced complexity, elucidating that firms tend to garner comparatively reduced profits within volatile environments. Significantly, the significance of R&D activities stems from their notable capacity to engender and propagate spillover effects throughout the supply chain. It is worthwhile to acknowledge that such activities can engender noticeable cost reductions for participating firms, a phenomenon often attributed to technological breaches or the sharing of erudite insights among researchers [7]. Market inquiry not only posits that R&D competition may yield greater financial gains vis-à-vis collaboration, as posited by [2], but also presents the inquiry into cooperative behaviors within a competitive R&D framework involving three prominent oligopolistic entities, as scrutinized by [8]. Nevertheless, it is incumbent upon us to underscore that R&D endeavors can yield intricate phenomena within the supply chain, as amply demonstrated by [9] investigation into the complexities that permeate a duopoly Stackelberg model of R&D competition. The contribution of R&D to the value creation process by precipitating conspicuous cost reductions across the entire supply chain remains an irrefutable fact. In this vein, an inquiry by [10] into the chaos that often pervades R&D initiatives within monopolistic firms and [11] exploration of the sophisticated dynamics at play within high-tech manufacturers substantiate this assertion.

The second stream of research focuses on the domain of chaos theory, which has garnered significant attention from scholars in recent years. Complexity is a pervasive phenomenon observed in economic and supply chain systems alike. Within chaotic systems, the sensitivity to initial conditions intensifies, leading to managerial challenges in decision-making processes [12]. Consequently, systems can display transitions between chaotic and stable states, underscoring the criticality of effective chaos control strategies. Notably, a growing number of researchers have adopted the framework of bounded rationality to investigate economic models, as exemplified by studies conducted by [13, 14]. The authors of [15] have analyzed the dynamic behavior of discretizing a continuous-time Leslie prey-predator model. The authors of [16] have examined complex behavior in investment patterns within spatial public goods games. These inquiries have shed light on the impact of bounded rationality on decision-making challenges within various market systems such as supply chains and platform ecosystems. Time delays and the influence of bounded rationality have been identified as key factors contributing to the intricate dynamics exhibited by these systems, including phenomena such as bifurcation and chaos. Consequently, research endeavors have proposed feedback control methods as viable means to address these complex behaviors. Notable studies by the authors of [1719], the authors of [19] have thoroughly examined the application and effectiveness of feedback control methods. Additionally, time-delayed feedback control (TDFC) has emerged as a prominent technique used to stabilize unstable periodic orbits within non-linear dynamical systems, as demonstrated by the work of [20]. Furthermore, the authors of [21], have proposed the incorporation of upper or lower bounds to alleviate chaos in dynamical systems, offering an alternative approach to chaos control.

In summary, despite the existing research on supply chain innovation and chaos dynamics in academia, there are certain deficiencies in their integration. Given the widespread phenomena and highlighted significance of collaborative R&D within the supply chain, related studies hold crucial significance. The bounded rationality exhibited by supply chain participants necessitates exploring the occurrences of excessive or insufficient innovation, resulting in heightened market volatility.

The remaining sections of this paper are structured as follows: Section 3 presents the R&D competition model, while Section 4 explores the dynamic analysis of the game, specifically highlighting the stable regions within the R&D competition game. Section 5 utilizes numerical simulations to illustrate the bifurcation diagrams, maximum Lyapunov exponents, and strange attractors. We implement feedback control on systems that have already entered chaotic states. The conclusions and managerial recommendations are provided in Section 6.

3. Model

This investigation establishes a comprehensive model of supply chain R&D competition, as graphically displayed in Figure 1. In this context, the supply chain configuration encompasses two manufacturers and two retailers, where the manufacturers strategically formulate R&D policies to effectively compete for market share by engaging the retailers as intermediaries. The structural framework of this discourse aligns closely with the pioneering contribution by [1]. The systemic dynamics of the supply chain R&D competition model follow a sequential game sequence, commencing with the manufacturers’ deliberation on their respective R&D levels. Subsequently, the manufacturers judiciously determine their wholesale prices, followed by the retailers’ formulation of optimal retail prices. Lastly, consumers exercise discernment in selecting their consumption tendencies.

Following the study by the authors of [22], retailers are confronted with a counter-demand function that can be represented as follows:where denotes the magnitude of the market and represents the quantity supplied by retailer i.

In the context of manufacturers’ R&D activities, spillover effects are present. To simplify the analysis, we assume equal spillover effects between the two firms. Consequently, the cost functions for the two retailers can be defined as follows:Here, signifies the extent of spillover effects, while corresponds to the cost incurred by retailer , and denotes the R&D level of manufacturer . It is worth noting that the R&D endeavors of the manufacturer yield cost reduction effects on both retailers.

For computational ease, we make the assumption that the marginal cost of the manufacturer is negligible. The profit functions of the manufacturer can be defined as follows:where represents the price set by manufacturer i and denotes the parameter for R&D cost. We refer to the cost function as outlined in [23], setting it to be quadratic, indicating the phenomenon of diminishing returns in research and development benefits.

The profit function for retailers is given by

By substituting equations (1) and (2) into equation (4), the retailer’s function can be derived as follows:

Taking the partial derivatives of in equation (5) with respect to , we obtain the necessary first-order conditions:

Solving these equations leads to the following solutions:

Substituting equation (7) back into equation (5), the resulting expressions for the manufacturer’s profit functions are as follows:

Finally, differentiating in equation (8) with respect to , we obtain the first-order necessary conditions:

The solutions for are given by

Substituting equation (10) back into equation (8), and differentiating with respect to , we obtain

Taking into account the practical constraints faced by manufacturers, namely, information and resource limitations, it becomes evident that arriving at entirely rational decisions is unattainable. Therefore, in line with the research conducted by [24], we adopt the assumption that each manufacturer operates under bounded rationality. This implies that manufacturers rely on previous-stage information when making R&D decisions. As a result, a dynamic system can be derived as follows:

In equation (12), represents the adjustment speed of manufacturer .

4. Equilibrium

Upon reaching a state of equilibrium in the R&D competition system, it becomes necessary to satisfy the following conditions: , . Subsequent calculations yield four fixed points: , , , , where

It is important to note that E1, E2, and E3 represent the corner solutions, bearing less significance in the context of R&D competition. Hence, our sole focus centers on the equilibrium solution E4, while analyzing the equilibrium conditions between the two manufacturers.

We can derive the equilibrium E4 in the R&D competition system. The Jacobian matrix can be expressed as follows:

The trace of the Jacobian matrix is calculated as follows:

The determinant is determined as follows:

Consequently, the characteristic polynomial of the Jacobian matrix can be expressed as follows:

By evaluating the expression , we can conclude that equation (17) has two real roots [24].

According to the Jury rule [24, 25], the stability condition for the R&D competition system states that

The condition (1) can be expressed as follows:

In order to satisfy this condition, it follows that

The condition (2) is given by

We can conclude that when , condition (2) is satisfied.

When , the condition (3) can be represented as follows:

We can conclude that

When ,

We can conclude that when ,

Figure 2 illustrates the distinct areas of stability: Area I represents a stable region, while Area II is characterized as unstable. In Area II, both conditions (1) and (2) are satisfied. Area III, on the other hand, falls within the realm of instability, meeting condition (2) but failing to satisfy conditions (1) and (3). Similarly, Area IV is unstable but complies with conditions (2) and (1), albeit falling short in satisfying condition (1) completely. By examining Figure 2, we discern that a low adjustment speed of manufacturers leads to a stable state within the R&D competition system. However, when the adjustment speed surpasses a certain threshold, the R&D competition system undergoes bifurcations or even transitions into chaotic states. These circumstances, in turn, pose challenges in managing the R&D level of manufacturers, thus increasing the complexities of their management.

5. Simulation

From the previous discussion, it is apparent that the R&D competition system may exhibit nonlinear behavior and potentially undergo bifurcation or even enter a chaotic state. To elucidate the impact of various factors in the system, numerical simulation methods are employed. In this section, our primary focus is on examining the influence of decision-making behavior and R&D characteristics on dynamic behavior. Decision-making behavior comprises the adjustment speed of manufacturers and the marginal cost of retailers, which can also serve as a representation of the market conditions faced by manufacturers. R&D characteristics primarily encompass the influence of spillover effects and R&D costs. There are four factors that impact the R&D competition system: adjustment speed, spillover effect, R&D cost, and retailer marginal cost.

We shall utilize a parameter set based on actual industry conditions. These parameters shall be incorporated into the R&D competition system (12) and subsequently subjected to computational simulation via MATLAB software. In the event of nonlinear behavior observed in the simulation outcomes, bifurcation and chaos phenomena manifest in the bifurcation diagram. This occurrence is accompanied by fluctuations in the maximum Lyapunov exponent, signifying an unstable phenomenon. Consequently, the predictability of corporate behavior diminishes, imposing heightened challenges for enterprise managers and resulting in consequential losses due to nonlinear behavior.

5.1. Adjustment Speed Effects

In this subsection, we illustrate the effects of manufacturer’s adjustment speed on stability. We utilize a fixed parameter set , with initial R&D levels set at and . Figure 3 demonstrates that, holding other parameters constant, an increase in the adjustment speed has a destabilizing effect.

Through numerical evidence of the complex dynamics in R&D competition system (12), we observe the bifurcation diagram of and concerning . Figure 3 reveals that the R&D competition system (12) remains stable when . In this stable state, the R&D level of manufacturer 1 exceeds that of manufacturer 2, possibly due to cost pressures leading to higher R&D level for manufacturer 1. When ranges from 1.342 to 1.649, the R&D competition system (12) undergoes a period-2 bifurcation. Subsequently, as , the R&D competition system (12) experiences a period-4 bifurcation. Ultimately, when , a state of chaos emerges. It is notable that within the stable regime, variations in the adjustment speed utilized by manufacturers do not significantly impact the changes in R&D level. However, when the adjustment speed surpasses an optimal threshold, the R&D competition system exhibits nonlinear behaviors, thereby rendering predictability of R&D actions arduous and exacerbating managerial complexities within manufacturers.

The largest Lyapunov exponent (LE) exhibits bifurcations and chaotic dynamics, whereby positive LE values indicate the occurrence of chaotic behavior. The LE can be understood as the exponential rate at which the infinitesimally small separation between two nearby initial states in the evolving phase space expands over time [26]. In Figure 4, the LE remains negative when , thus indicating the stability of the R&D competition system (12) due to the low adjustment speed of . When approximates 1.342 and 1.649, the LE attains a zero value, suggesting the onset of bifurcation within the R&D competition system (12). Beyond , the LE primarily assumes positive values, signifying the entrance into a chaotic regime for the R&D competition system (12). Figure 5 visually presents the manifestation of strange attractors in the R&D competition system (12) at . Additionally, Figure 5 demonstrates the partial synchronization of and during the state of chaos within the R&D competition system (12).

Figure 6 depicts the aggregate profits of Manufacturer 1 over 100 iterations based on the adjustment speed. As the adjustment speed increases, Manufacturer 1 eventually enters a chaotic state. It is evident that the adjustment speed has no impact on profit variations when the R&D competition system is in a stable state. However, following the occurrence of bifurcation, Manufacturer 1 experiences a significant decline in profits. This observation implies that while the adjustment speed does not affect the R&D level to a certain extent, the nonlinear behavior results in profit losses throughout the entire supply chain. Moreover, it introduces greater management challenges for manufacturers within the supply chain.

5.2. Retailer Marginal Cost Effect

In this section, we elucidate the influence of retailer marginal cost on the stability of R&D competition system (12). The simulation in this section aligns closely with the previously presented data. We constrain the parameters to the following values: , and initialize the R&D level with and . With the purpose of providing a fully representation of the impact of market capability on dynamic behavior, we judiciously adjust the prior adjustment speed, accentuating the increase in retailer 2’s adjustment speed. Consequently, the R&D competition system’s precariousness rises, which enhances the manifestation of chaotic phenomena, while preserving its evolutionary tendencies intact. Figure 7 substantiates the realization of stability in R&D competition system (12) in response to inflated retailer marginal costs.

Within Figure 7, we peruse the comprehensive bifurcation diagram depicting and as nuanced by retailer 1’s marginal cost . Ascertained therein is the R&D competition system’s manifestation of chaotic behavior for values less than 0.605, transmuting into a bifurcation regime within the range of . Profoundly, when exceeds the threshold of 2.251, the R&D competition system (12) stabilizes. It is pertinent to note that, during this phase of stability, retailer 1’s marginal cost escalation precipitates the decrement of and the concomitant increment of . Evidently, greater retailer marginal costs instigate R&D competition system stability, implying that a stronger market advantage paradoxically engenders a heightened propensity towards chaotic dynamics.

Figure 8 presents the Lyapunov exponent (LE) in relation to retailer marginal cost. For values less than 0.605, the LE exhibits negative values, indicating the R&D competition system (12) displays chaotic behavior. At approximately and , the LE assumes a value of zero, signaling a transition to bifurcation in R&D competition system (12). Beyond , the LE reverts to negative values, suggesting the R&D competition system (12) attains stability. Figure 9 showcases the strange attractors of R&D competition system (12) at .

Figure 10 portrays the aggregate profit of Manufacturer 1 over 100 iterations in relation to the impact of Retailer 1’s marginal cost. It is evident that as Retailer 1’s marginal cost escalates, Manufacturer 1’s aggregate profit diminishes. While reducing marginal cost may seem economically advantageous, it proves deleterious to system stability. As previously expounded, the market influence of R&D manufacturers directly affects their R&D levels. Greater market influence corresponds to higher levels of R&D, resulting in maximal profits. However, it is crucial to recognize that such a scenario also engenders a heightened inclination towards system instability. Under these circumstances, manufacturers must strive to strike a balance among their R&D decisions, profitability, and market stability.

5.3. Spillover Effects

This analysis examines the influence of spillover effects on the profitability and stability of R&D competition systems. Utilizing the fixed parameter set , we consider the initial R&D levels as and . We adjust the speed of adaptation to yield an uninterrupted visualization of the occurrence of chaotic phenomena.

Figure 11 presents the bifurcation diagram of and with respect to the spillover effects, providing insight into the stability of the R&D competition system (12). Stability is achieved when , during which the Nash equilibrium point E4 remains locally stable. Specifically, for , the R&D competition system (12) undergoes a transition into a 2-period bifurcation, while for , it exhibits chaotic behavior. Notably, due to their lower R&D costs, Manufacturer 1 gains a competitive advantage in innovation, surpassing Manufacturer 2 in terms of R&D levels. However, as spillover effects increase, Manufacturer 1 experiences a decline in R&D level, while Manufacturer 2 sees an improvement. Figure 11 illustrates that, while holding other parameters constant, an increase in spillover effects leads to instability in the R&D competition system (12). Noteworthy is the supply chain system’s bifurcation and resulting instability when spillover effects are high, culminating in intermittent chaos within the R&D competition system [27].

Figure 12 showcases the Lyapunov exponent (LE) as it pertains to . Notably, the LE denoted values below zero when α < 0.437, shedding light on the inherent stability of the R&D competition system (12) amidst low spillover effects. A threshold is observed at , where the LE converges to zero, implying the emergence of a two-period bifurcation within the R&D competition system (12). Upon exceeding , the LE predominantly assumes positive values, signifying the R&D competition system’s entry into a chaotic domain. Figure 8 effectively captures the intermittent chaos traits distinctly manifested in the R&D competition system. In parallel, Figure 13 visually delineates the strange attractors of the R&D competition system (12) at . Moreover, Figure 13 underscores the coalescence between and under chaotic circumstances within R&D competition system (12).

Figure 14 visually represents the aggregate profit of Manufacturer 1 over 100 iterations, elucidating its dependency on the spillover effect. Notably, a positive correlation is observed between Manufacturer 1’s aggregate profit and the magnitude of spillover. Contrary to alternative scholarly findings, an increase in spillover effects among distinct manufacturers yields a collective rise in their profits. However, as the spillover effect intensifies, the R&D competition system experiences bifurcations, impeding the rate of profit escalation. Simultaneously, the occurrence of these bifurcations leads to an augmented burden of managerial costs. Consequently, prudent supply chain managers are compelled to impose limitations on the intensity of spillover effects.

5.4. R&D Cost Effects

This section presents a comprehensive analysis of the influence of R&D costs on the stability of R&D competition system (12). The specified parameter set is held constant, while the initial R&D levels are set as and . Consistent with the preceding discourse, adaptations are made to the adjustment speed, while maintaining the constancy of the remaining coefficients. Figure 15 visually portrays the R&D competition system’s response to varying R&D costs, revealing the attainment of stability as these costs escalate.

In Figure 15, the bifurcation diagram of and is presented in relation to Manufacturer 1’s R&D cost. It is evident that the R&D competition system (12) manifests a state of chaos when , transitions into a state of bifurcation for , and ultimately achieves stability when . Under stable area, an increase in Manufacturer 1’s R&D cost leads to a decrease in and an increase in . Notably, this observation reflects the occurrence of intense market competition and potential chaos when R&D costs are low, ultimately giving way to a more stable system when R&D costs are relatively high. Moreover, it underscores the significance of enhancing R&D capabilities for manufacturers striving to maintain a competitive edge.

Figure 16 depicts the Lyapunov exponent (LE) in relation to : for , the LE exceeds zero, indicating chaotic behavior in R&D competition system (12). At approximately , the LE reaches zero, signifying the onset of bifurcation in the system. As surpasses the threshold of 0.446, the LE becomes negative, indicating R&D competition system (12) attains stability. Figure 17 illustrates the emergence of strange attractors in R&D competition system (12) when .

Figure 18 depicts the progressive variation of manufacturer 1’s aggregate profit over 100 iterations in response to changes in its R&D cost. A discernible pattern emerges, revealing a negative relationship between Manufacturer 1’s R&D cost and its aggregate profit. Specifically, as the R&D cost increases, the aggregate profit experiences a consistent decline. This finding underscores the intricate trade-off between profitability and stability within the context of R&D investment. Notably, when the R&D cost is low, the R&D competition system achieves a relatively higher profit level. However, this regime also coincides with a greater propensity for bifurcation and chaotic phenomena. Conversely, when the R&D cost is set at a higher value, the R&D competition system gravitates towards stability but at the expense of diminished profitability. Thus, it becomes imperative for manufacturers to diligently strike a delicate equilibrium between sustaining profitability and ensuring system stability.

5.5. Time-Delayed Feedback Control

Based on the preceding discourse, it is discernible that under specific circumstances, the R&D competition system manifests phenomena characterized by bifurcation and chaos. These phenomena yield a deleterious impact on the profitability of the R&D competition system, thereby posing formidable challenges to the management of the supply chain. To effectively govern the chaos and curtail financial losses with the manufacturers, the adoption of control mechanisms emerges as a customary choice. Within the context of Section 5.1, the R&D competition system (12) transitions into a state of chaos. To ameliorate this condition, we employ the Time-Delay Feedback Control (TDFC) method, as expounded by [27], as a means of mitigating the chaotic state prevalent in R&D competition system. Mathematically, the TDFC mechanism can be characterized by the equation , where the parameter assumes the role of the chaos control parameter. As a consequence, the R&D competition system (12) undergoes a transformation. Notably, the ensuing R&D TDFC system can be succinctly presented as follows:

So we get the R&D TDFC system as follows:

In accordance with Section 4.1, the parameter set was established as fixed, while the initial R&D levels assumed values of and . As an outcome of this configuration, the R&D competition system demonstrated a state of chaos. Figure 19 effectively portrays the bifurcation diagram and the corresponding Lyapunov exponent (LE) in relation to the parameter . A detailed scrutiny unveils that the R&D competition TDFC system devolves into a state of chaos when assumes values below the threshold of 0.056, exhibits bifurcation within the parameter range of , and ultimately achieves stability when surpasses the value of 0.366. Employing the TDFC method proves instrumental in attenuating intricate occurrences, namely bifurcation and chaos, without imposing any perceivable detriment upon the equilibrium state and its correlated innovation quotient.

In Figure 20, the absence of the TDFC mechanism elicits a chaotic state with . Continuing along this line of inquiry, subsequent explorations are undertaken for two distinct scenarios, where is set at 0.2 and 0.5, respectively. The acquisition of empirical evidence conclusively affirms that upon setting equal to 0.2, the R&D competition TDFC system undergoes a two-period bifurcation, whereas an unequivocally stable state is attained as acquires the value of 0.5.

6. Conclusions and Discussion

6.1. Conclusions

This study explores the stability of the R&D competition model within the context of the supply chain. It has been observed that four influential factors, namely adjustment speed, spillover effect, R&D cost effect, and retailer marginal cost, significantly impact the stability of the R&D system. Through simulated simulation of these factors, it has been ascertained that an escalation in adjustment speed and spillover effects precipitates a state of bifurcation, leading ultimately to the onset of a chaotic state in the R&D competition system. The adjustment speed does not exert any influence on the equilibrium R&D level; however, the occurrence of complex phenomena, such as bifurcation, yields a decline in manufacturer profits. Additionally, the spillover effect heightens the R&D level, resulting in augmented profits. Nevertheless, when this effect surpasses a certain threshold, R&D competition system instability ensues, thereby impeding profit growth rates. Conversely, elevations in R&D cost and retailer marginal cost promote the R&D competition system stability; nonetheless, they concomitantly give rise to diminished manufacturer profits. To combat the issue of chaotic dynamics, the TDFC mechanism has been introduced, which effectively mitigates chaos.

6.2. Theoretical Contributions

Our study makes theoretical contributions in the following aspects: (1) We investigate the stability of R&D competition within the context of the supply chain, extending upon prior works such as [23, 28], by integrating R&D competition, chaos theory, and the supply chain. (2) We enhance our understanding of the stability of the R&D competition system in the supply chain, shedding light on the origins of R&D competition system instability and providing valuable insights for further advancement of R&D practices. (3) We provide a foundation for managerial decision-making by examining critical factors influencing R&D behavior, including adjustment speed, spillover effects, R&D costs, and retailer marginal costs. (4) Recognizing the trade-off between profit and stability, we propose the TDFC mechanism as an effective tool to alleviate chaos, aiming to enrich R&D research with the integration of chaos theory.

6.3. Managerial Implications

Our research yields managerial implications for supply chain decision-making: First, we find that the R&D competition system becomes chaotic and loses control when the retailer’s marginal cost reaches a sufficiently low level. This indicates that supply chain innovation must necessarily take into account the retailer costs. When retailer costs are excessively reduced, such as in the case of team buying, it can lead to complex behaviors. At this time, the business model represented by team buying, which excessively relies on the cost-driven operating model, should be moderately controlled. Retailers with cost advantages may introduce complexities to the R&D competition system. Therefore, managers should carefully balance manufacturer profitability and stability. Second, although chaos may emerge in simulations, we conclude that the chaotic state can be effectively managed through the implementation of the TDFC method. Managers should consider the adoption of similar control mechanisms to mitigate chaotic behaviors and enhance system stability.

6.4. Limitations and Further Research

This paper acknowledges several limitations. First, our R&D competition model assumes symmetry in the spillover effects among firms. However, in the real world, different firms may exhibit diverse spillover effects with each other, leading to potentially more interesting conclusions. Second, our assumption of collaboration between manufacturers and retailers overlooks power dynamics and possible competition between them. It is essential to pay closer attention to this aspect, as it is likely to yield more intriguing findings.

Data Availability

The data that supports the findings of this study are available upon request from the author Jianli Xiao at [email protected].

Disclosure

During the preparation of this work, the authors used ChatGPT in order to improve language. After using this service, the authors reviewed and edited the content as needed and take full responsibility for the content of the publication.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare that there are no conflicts of interest.

Authors’ Contributions

Conceptualization was done by J.X. and H.X.; methodology was proposed by J.X.; software was handled by J.X.; J.X. wrote the original draft; J.X. reviewed and edited the paper; visualization was done by H.X.; and funding acquisition was done by J.X. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Acknowledgments

This research was supported by the Research Initiation Foundation Project of Yiwu Industrial & Commercial College (RCKY202309).