Abstract

Two financing modes can be considered for manufacturer’s production capital constrained: RPFM (retailer’s prepayment financing mode) and PCFM (procurement contract financing mode). Under the RPFM, the retailer places order in advance for a discount price and makes prepayment; manufacturer is able to finance from a bank as production quantity cannot satisfy the second-order quantity of retailer. By contrast, manufacturers make financing from commercial banks based on the procurement contract with upstream supplier under the PCFM. Taking into account the relation between production volumes with the manufacturer’s own capital and retailer’s order quantity, the optimal production and financing decision model for manufacturer under these two financing modes are built. Moreover, the profits of the manufacturer, the retailer, and the supply chain are compared and discussed. Results show that both of the two modes can create new value and profit for the supply chain with capital constraint and achieve optimal production under “newsvendor” mode; the supply chain has the better performance under the RPFM than that achieved under the PCFM. Also, under the RPFM, the manufacturer’s production and the profit of the whole supply chain would be increased when the manufacturer makes the second financing. Similar conclusion is reached under the PCFM. Finally, numerical study was given to demonstrate the conclusions.

1. Introduction

A manufacturer with capital constraint restricts its own production capacity and fails to meet retailer’s order demands. For manufacturer with capital constraint, there are two financing modes commonly used: retailer’ prepayment and manufacturer’s financing from commercial banks. Two factors make the retailer be willing to provide working capital to the manufacturer. On the one hand, it stabilizes purchasing channel, ensures goods source quality, and maintains the long-term cooperation relationship with the enterprises; on the other hand, the retailer can get some discount from the manufacturer. With regard to the manufacturer, by selecting retailer’s prepayment financing, it gets the needed production capital, ensures smooth selling channel, and gets sales volume in advance. For example, the large retail enterprise, such as Carrefour, Wal-Mart, and Wu-Mart, makes credit rating for upstream manufacturers or suppliers and provides capital support with their own capital. However, the prepayment financing mode is often under the precondition of the manufacturer’s discount on the supplied goods, which often reduces profit margin of the manufacturer. Hence, the manufacturer often considers finance from financial institutes, which becomes a preferred way of corporate financing. To avoid credit risk, financial institutes represented by commercial banks often need a third party to provide security or pledge for the loan enterprises. With emerging of the innovative financing service in the supply chain, financing from the bank based on interenterprise relationship becomes a new option for capital-constrained enterprises and a new profit increasing point for commercial banks.

In the field of corporate finance research, owing to the M&M theory’s assumption that corporate investment and financing are independent from production and operation [1], capital management in supply chain has long been ignored. However, the factors such as agent cost, information asymmetry, and tax make the capital structure of enterprise be closely related to the production decision [2]. Studies show that capital constraint will impact on enterprise’s operation decision, while financing service can create new value to realize optimal decision and achieve the supply chain coordination [35].

Supply chain financing mainly focuses on the optimal decision and financing strategy selection under internal and external financing modes. Relying on interenterprise trade relation in the supply chain, the commercial credit mode could satisfy capital demand of enterprises. Commercial credit financing has appellations such as delay payment, trade financing, and postponement strategy [6], which are all regarded as short-term financing methods. When the buyer is capital constrained, upstream manufacturer or supplier may provide credit financing by this financing mode. Studies show that commercial credit financing could stimulate the retailers’ order and expand market share for suppliers and is an important financing method for the buyer [7, 8]. Studies on commercial credit mode mainly include optimal decision about credit term [9], order policy [10, 11], and optimal batch size [12]. The above studies mainly focus on downstream retailer with capital constraint and rarely focus on commercial credit financing when manufacturer faces capital constraint. Besides, commercial credit financing is also an important way for supply chain coordination with capital constraint. For example, Lee and Rhee showed that the trade credit contract can better coordinate supply than commercial bank financing where both retailer and manufacturer are capital constrained [13]. Chen and Wang indicated that commercial credit can create value for supply chain and partially coordinate supply chain with capital constrained [14].

External financing via interenterprise relation is another important way for capital-constrained supply chain. In the production phase from cash payment to product selling, the enterprise may get credit from external financial institute with inventory pledge or warehouse receipt pledge. For example, Buzacott and Zhang connected asset financing to production decision and built model with available cash as assets and liabilities; meanwhile, outstanding loans under different interest rates were taken into account [15]. The study indicated the importance of simultaneously considering production and financing strategies. Under financing mode with pledge by warehouse receipts and taking into account the bankrupt risk of retailer, Yan and Sun studied optimal credit decision of commercial bank, optimal wholesale price of manufacturer, and optimal order quality of retailer [16]. Yan and Sun make a comparison between two different limited financing modes where retailer is capital constrained and consider the bankruptcy risk; the results have shown that the two financing modes all can improve the expected profits of supply chain [17].

In addition, enterprise can get guarantee based on the cooperation relation between upstream and downstream enterprises, so as to finance from commercial bank. For example, Yi and Zhou considered the decision of inventory pledge financing from commercial bank under core enterprise’s buy-back [18]. Zhang and Tang considered the supply chain financing decision of financing from commercial bank under manufacturer’s guarantee where retailer is capital constrained and made decision for optimal order quantity of retailer and optimal order price of manufacturer [19]. Moreover, financing from commercial bank with procurement relation between upstream and downstream enterprises raises more and more academic concern recently. Downstream enterprise requests credit loan towards commercial bank and the latter checks the trade relation between upstream and downstream enterprises. Then, when downstream enterprise pays cash deposit in certain rate, the commercial bank will pay for the raw materials purchased for upstream enterprise, and the upstream enterprise should store such raw materials in warehouse specified by the commercial bank. At last, commercial bank gets back the capital by controlling downstream enterprise’s right of taking delivery of goods. The related studies refer to [20, 21].

For supply chain enterprise facing capital constraint, different research on the question of which financial methods should be adopted has different conclusions. Zhou and Groenevelt compared trade financing and bank financing from perspective of asset pledge. They draw a conclusion that commercial bank credit is more attractive than trade credit [22]. Jing et al. indicate that, as higher wholesale price is required, commercial bank financing is superior to commercial credit financing. When the production cost is low, commercial credit financing can uniquely achieve equilibrium [23]. However, according to the information superiority theory, supplier can collect normal business information of retailer more easily than the bank in credit loan. In case of default of the retailer, the supplier can take the advantage of disposing products; meanwhile, choosing credit loan represents confidence of the supplier in its products, which could facilitate control on trade relation of the supply chain [24]. In addition, Caldentey and Chen indicate that, for the retailer, internal financing from supplier is superior to external financing from commercial bank [25]. Kouvelis and Zhao indicated that manufacturer can improve profit of supply chain by selecting commercial credit financing and retailer financing from manufacturer better than from commercial bank [26]. Chen made a comparison between commercial credit financing and bank financing and pointed out that commercial credit financing can uniquely achieve equilibrium [27]. Yan et al. designed a partial trade credit guarantee contract for the coordination of supply chain finance (SCF) system where the retailer is capital constrained [28]. The results have shown that this contract can realize profit maximization of supply chain and achieve the coordination and financing equilibrium for SCF system based on a suitable guarantee coefficient.

Current studies on supply chain financing are mainly based on the assumption of buyer’s capital constraint and mainly focus on these issues: optimal order quantity, retailer’s order strategy, and the financing decision and coordination under these two financing modes. Rare studies focus on optimal decision and financing strategy selection of manufacturer under capital constraint. Wang et al. establish a conditional and partial trade credit model, where the supplier is capital constrained and as the leader in the Stackelberg model [29]. This model makes the supply chain more stable and a win-win outcome can be realized and the supplier’s financial pressure can be relieved. Under the condition that manufacturer specifies quantity discount rate, Zeng and Luo designed trade credit incentive mechanism for retailer to make prepayment to the manufacturer and studied inventory management and coordination of supply chain. They reached the conclusion that, if the manufacturer got high profit, the mechanism could achieve coordination of the entire supply chain and Pareto Optimality [30]. In addition, Wang and Luo studied the optimal production decision and financing strategy selection of manufacturer under two financing modes, retailer’s prepayment financing model (RPFM) and supplier’s commercial bank loan under retailer’s guarantee, when supplier faced capital constraint. The result indicates that the two financing modes can both realize optimal production under noncapital constraint; moreover, when retailer cost is lower than bank loan interest, retailer’s prepayment financing mode should be selected; otherwise, commercial bank financing under retailer’s guarantee should be adopted [31]. Zhan et al. made a comparison and analyzed manufacturer’s production decision and retailer’s financing problem under the RPFM and commercial bank financing, which further considered the price discount for retailer’s prepayment. The result shows that both modes could create value for supply chain, and prepayment financing could be better than financing from bank when interest rate is specified and price discount rate meets certain requirements [32]. In addition, Xiao and Luo made a further research of dual-channel supply chain and get the similar results that the retailer’s prepayment financing mode (RPFM) is better than financing from bank when manufacturer is capital constrained under the condition that the discount rate is equal to the bank rate [33].

References [31, 32] are most closely related to this study. However, the difference is that, in the above literatures, further discussion is needed on the problem whether manufacturer’s own capital could satisfy order demand of retailer or no. In addition, with the RPFM, in case of secondary order from retailer, the manufacturer needs to make secondary financing from commercial bank for further production. In this case, how could the manufacturer select financing strategy and how to make optimal production? Aiming at the problem, under procurement contract financing mode (PCFM), the question of whether the manufacturer’s own capital could satisfy retailer’s order is discussed. Furthermore, we studied the optimal production and financing strategy of manufacturer and made a comparison analysis on supply chain performances between RPFM and PCFM.

The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. Section 2 describes the studied problem and symbols involved in modeling and illustrates assumptions and basic models in the paper. Sections 3 and 4 present supply chain financing decision models under RPFM and under RPFM, respectively. Section 5 compares the supply chain performances under these two financing modes; Section 6 presents a numerical example. The last section is the conclusion.

2. Problem Description and Basic Model

2.1. Problem Description and Notations

In the supply chain system constituted by a single supplier, manufacturer, and the retailer, the upstream supplier and downstream retailer have commercial credit and stable operational cash flow. The manufacturer purchases raw materials from a supplier to produce certain products and sells to the retailer who faces uncertain demands. It is assumed that, during the entire procurement, manufacturing, and selling processes, the manufacturer is required to solve the capital constraint through financing.

In case of capital constraint, the manufacturer should determine production after receiving an order request from the retailer. And its own capital may be insufficient to cover the procurement cost for the order quantity. The problems to be considered by the manufacturer during financing decision-making are as follows. Under the precondition of ordering a certain quantity of products with wholesale price discount, the retailer may make prepayment. However, in case of secondary order when the sales volume exceeds order quantity, the retailer will no longer enjoy a price discount. Moreover, if its own capital is insufficient for secondary production, the manufacturer needs to make the secondary financing. In this case, the manufacturer may rely on the procurement contract with upstream supplier and get credit loan from the bank. We called this mode as retailer’s prepayment financing mode (RPFM).

In addition, the manufacturer could get credit loan directly from commercial bank through procurement contract with upstream suppler and should pay initial deposit to the bank in certain ratio; then, after check procurement contract between supplier and manufacturer, the bank provides loan in certain interest rate for payment of the capital needed by manufacturer in production. Besides, the manufacturer should store the raw materials in logistics enterprise specified by a commercial bank, while the bank will control the capital recycling through the right of taking delivery of goods. We called this mode as procurement contract financing mode (PCFM). Figure 1 demonstrates the specific frame and flow.

In this paper, notations and symbols are shown in Notations.

2.2. Assumptions and Basic Model

Assumption 1. The supplier, manufacturer, and retailer are all risk-neutral and have perfect rationality.

Assumption 2. The information among supplier, manufacturer, and retailer is symmetrical with no information concealment.

Assumption 3. The product residual value is zero and reputation loss caused by stockout is not taken into account.

Assumption 4. The supplier, manufacturer, and retailer all comply with the laws in operation and financing and no one breaks the contract.

Assumption 5. The manufacturer just has only financing chance when the retailer is reordering under RPFM.

Without capital constraint, the manufacturer’s production satisfies the retailers order demand. It means that retailer’s order complies with the “newsvendor” mode [32]. Expected profits of retailer, manufacturer, and supply chain are

When the manufacturer is capital constrained, and order demand of retailer exceeds the maximum production of manufacturer with its own capital (i.e., ), expected profits of retailer, manufacturer, and the whole supply chain are

Obviously, as , capital constraint results in failure of manufacturer in satisfying the retailer’s optimal order and making retailer, manufacturer, and the whole supply chain be incapable of realizing optimal profits under “newsvendor” model.

3. Supply Chain Financing Decision under RPFM

3.1. Manufacturer’s Profit and Decision

Under the RPFM, the retailer and manufacturer share market demand information. The financing and production decision sequence is as follows. The retailer determines order quantity and makes payment for ; in case of secondary order of retailer, for (wherein, ), the manufacturer’s capital satisfies second-order demand, and the manufacturer cannot need financing; for , the manufacturer considers secondary financing for production; for , which means market demand exceeds production of manufacturer, the production is .

() For , the prepayment could be sufficient for the manufacturer to meet retailer’s demand, and manufacturer’s profit is written as .

() For , the manufacturer satisfies the secondary order demand with its own capital and does not need secondary financing, and manufacturer’s profit is .

() For , the manufacturer’s own capital could not satisfy the secondary order demand and will need secondary financing. In this case, initial deposit should be provided to bank in certain rate of total procurement value to be paid to upstream enterprise. is the loan amount from bank. After checking procurement contract and relationship, the bank will directly make payment to supplier, where is loan interest rate. The manufacturer starts secondary production after receiving raw materials needed. And manufacturer’s profit is as follows:

() For , the market demand exceeds the maximum production volume of manufacturer after financing. In this case, the manufacturer’s profit is .

In summary, the profit of manufacturer can be given by Therefore, decision model of the manufacturer is given as follows:

Obviously, we have , it is easy to observe that Formula (5) is linear constraint, which is nonlinear convex programming with respect to , and the manufacturer’s optimal production quantity is

Conclusion 1. When , that is, , the manufacturer will choose loan from commercial bank. The optimal loan amount is

3.2. Retailer’s Profit and Decision

At the beginning of selling season, the retailer enters into order agreement with the manufacturer, makes prepayment for the manufacturer to carry out production, and places preorder in discount price; the retailer faces random market demand . For , the retailer should dispose the remaining products by himself and never return them to the manufacturer; for , the retailer needs to make the secondary order in price and will no longer enjoy discount. If the market demand exceeds the maximum quantity available in the secondary order, the retailer will bear the loss caused by stockout. Therefore, the final order quantity of retailer is , and the profit is

The retailer’s expected profit model is given by Substituting (6) into (9), the following can be obtained.

() For , holds. From the first-order optimality condition, we have , where .

() For , holds. From the first-order optimality condition, , where .

() For , holds. From the first-order optimality condition, we have , where

() For is the convex function of preorder quantity with respect to . Then, taking the first-order derivative with respect to , we havewhere .

Equation (12) is rewritten as

If satisfies , we can deduce

The optimal order quantity is given by where is the positive solution as the following equation:

Accordingly, substituting (15) into (6) the optimal production volume of manufacturer is rewritten as follows:

From (15) and (17), the optimal order quantity and production volume are both related to wholesale discount coefficient .

Proposition 1. For IFR distributions of demand, if and , then we have . If , the sufficient condition for isConversely, if where is the positive solution of (16).

Proof. The following results are obtained from (15).
() For , holds.
() For , we have
() For , by taking the first-order derivation of (16) with respect to , we deduceObviously, if the distribution of demand is IFR, is equivalent to the following inequality:Conversely, ; then we have

Conclusion 2. From Proposition 1, the optimal order quantity under prepayment is negatively related to the discount rate ; that is, larger discount rate value represents smaller discount rate and leads to smaller optimal order quantity . On the contrary, smaller discount rate value represents larger discount rate and leads to larger optimal order quantity .

Proposition 2. For IFR distributions of demand, if credit loan is constant, the retailer’s profit is a decreasing function with respect to and satisfies the following formula: where is the positive solution of (16).

Proof. () For , holds.
() For , holds.
() For , , we haveIn summary, if the distribution of demand is IFR, holds, and is a decreasing function with respect to .

Proposition 3. For IFR distributions of demand, if credit loan is a constant, then the manufacturer’s profit is an increasing function about and can be given bywhere is the positive solution of (16).

Proof. () For , from the conclusion of Proposition 1, we have () For and , from the conclusion of Proposition 1, we have () For and In summary, if the distribution of demand is IFR, holds. The manufacturer’s profit is an increasing function with respect to .

4. Supply Chain Decision under PCFM

Manufacturer with capital constraint also can select requesting credit loan directly from commercial bank with PCFM. After checking the relation between manufacturer and supplier, the commercial bank provides certain loan to the manufacturer who should repay the capital and interest at the end of the selling season. To avoid default risk, sales income should be greater than the capital and interest to be repaid; that is, . At the beginning of selling season, the retailer orders products with quantity of from the manufacturer at wholesale price , where the manufacturer production volume is .

At the beginning of selling season, the retailer places purchase order with amount of from the manufacturer according to its judgment on market demand and production capacity of the manufacturer. For , the manufacturer could satisfy the retailer’s order demand with its own capital; for , the manufacturer could satisfy retailer’s order demand through loan; for , the order quantity of retailer exceeds the manufacturer’s maximum production volume after financing. In this case, the retailer will be out of stock with unit cost . Profit of the retailer can be given by

The excepted profit of retailer under PCFM is as follows:

In initial production period, after receiving order from the retailer, decision sequence of the manufacturer is as follows: for , the manufacturer could satisfy the retailer’s order demand with its own capital and does not need financing; for , the manufacturer could satisfy the retailer’s order demand through loan; for , the order quantity of retailer exceeds the maximum production volume of manufacturer after financing. Production volume of the manufacturer is .

() For , the manufacturer does not need financing; that is, it could satisfy the retailer’s order demand with its own capital. Manufacturer’s profit is .

() For , the manufacturer needs loan from bank and should repay the capital and interest at the end of sales season. Manufacturer’s profit is .

() For , the order quantity exceeds the manufacturer’s maximum production volume with loan. Manufacturer’s profit is .

Therefore, manufacturer’s profit under PCFM is as follows:

Decision model of manufacturer is given by

Owning to the fact that and the constraint conditions are linear constraint conditions of , (32) is a nonlinear convex programming problem about . According to Kuhn-Tucker conditions, the manufacturer’s optimal production volume is

Proposition 4. Under PCFM, if the manufacturer carries out production according to , the optimal loan amount is as follows:

Proof. () For , holds. From the first-order optimality condition,We haveand .
() For , holds. From the first-order optimum condition, So, the manufacture should try to satisfy the production demand with loan from commercial bank, and the optimal loan amount is .
(3) For , is obtained. According to the first-order optimum condition , the optimal loan amount should not exist in this case, because of .

5. Comparison of Supply Chain Performances

Considering the goal of maximizing profit of the whole supply chain and the profits under the conditions of no capital constraint, RPFM and PCFM are compared.

Under RPFM, is the maximum value point and . For , the manufacturer does not need loan: that is, . For , commercial bank loan can be expressed as .

Under PFCM, the maximum production capacity of manufacturer is , and the loan from commercial bank is . By comparing profits of the supply chain, we can get the following conclusions.

Proposition 5. In case of capital constraint, under RPFM, we have . And for , we have . Under PCFM, similarly, . Besides, for , we have ; for , RPFM and PCFM have the same optimal production volume and .

Proof. Firstly, if the manufacturer adopts RPFM, from the assumption, the manufacturer’s optimal production volume holds.
() For , we haveTherefore, it is easy to observe .
() For , we haveTherefore, for , holds.
In addition, the manufacturer’s maximum production volume is under PCFM. According to the assumption, , and the loan amount is . We deduceFor , holds.
Furthermore, we can get the result of the supply chain profits under two financing modes as follows.
() For ,and we get .
() For ,So, holds.
According to the conclusion of Proposition 5, both the two financing modes can create new value and profit for the supply chain under capital constraint and can achieve the optimal production when there is no capital constraint. If the secondary financing is needed when their own capital could not satisfy the second-order demand, the manufactures need the second financing, and the loan interest rate meets certain requirements, the RPFM can increase production volume of the manufacturer and increase profit of the entire supply chain; the corresponding conclusion can also be reached under PCFM. By comparing these two financing modes, the whole supply chain performance is better than that with financing from a commercial bank by PCFM. Therefore, the RPFM should be adopted.

6. Numerical Example and Analysis

6.1. Parameter Setting

To ensure consistency of the study, it is assumed that the market demand on certain product of the manufacturer satisfies the uniform distribution in [, ], the unit market sale price , the unit wholesale price , the unit stock out cost , manufacturer’s unit production cost , loan interest rate of commercial bank , manufacturer’s own capital amount , and production volume with its own capital .

6.2. Numerical Example

When there is no capital constraint and the manufacturer carries out optimal production according to classic “newsvendor” model, the optimal production volume and expected profits of manufacturer, retailer, and the whole supply chain are calculated as follows: , , , and . Under capital constraint, if the manufacturer produces with its own capital, expected profits of manufacturer, retailer, and the entire supply chain are , , and , respectively. Obviously, in case of capital constraint, the manufacturer, retailer, and the entire supply chain cannot achieve the expected optimal profits.

Under the RPFM, the manufacturer’s optimal production volume and retailer’s order quantity are related to the discount coefficient. By verifying Formula (17), after secondary financing, the manufacturer could realize optimal production and not all the loan from the secondary financing is used in production.

Under the PCFM, from (33) and (34), is verified satisfying the conditions; in this case, we have . Figure 2 shows the optimal production volumes of manufacturer under the two financing modes.

From Figure 2, under the RPFM, the optimal production volume decreases with increase of discount coefficient , presenting negative correlation: that is, high discount price required by the retailer will lead to low wholesale price and high optimal production volume of the manufacturer. In addition, the manufacturer can achieve the optimal production volume under both financing modes.

Under the RPFM, the relation between and the discount price is illustrated in Figure 3, so as to show the influence of discount coefficient on retailer’s order quantity.

From Figure 3, under the RPFM, is negative correlation with the discount coefficient . Besides, if the manufacturer could satisfy retailer’s secondary order with own capital, for , the production volume with its own capital is less than retailer’s order quantity. To increase production and sales volume, the manufacturer should adopt RPFM. For , the production volume with the manufacturer’s own capital is more than retailer’s order quantity under RPFM. With large bargaining space, the manufacturer may choose whether to accept preorder request of the retailer in discount price.

Changes in expected optimal profit of manufacturer under two financing modes are shown in Figure 4.

From Figure 4, the expected profits of the manufacturer under the both modes are lower than that under classic “newsvendor” model, and the profit under RPFM is also lower than that with the manufacture’s own capital. In addition, with different optimal production volumes, preorder volumes, and discount coefficients, the manufacturer will choose different financing modes.

Figure 5 shows expected profits of retailer under two modes.

From Figure 5, the retailer’s profits under both financing modes are higher than that under classic “newsvendor” model and the manufacturer’s optimal profit with own capital. No matter which financing mode is then adopted by the manufacturer, the retailer’s profits can always increase. Moreover, under the RPFM, retailer’s expected profit will decrease with increase of discount coefficient.

The optimal expected profits of supply under the two financing modes are compared (as shown in Figure 6).

Figure 6 shows that, under the RPFM, profits of the supply chain are more than those under classic “newsvendor” model and the PCFM. For , profits of the supply chain can reach the maximum value and will decrease with increase of discount coefficient , which also indicates that the larger discount will lead to higher profit of the supply chain. It is a remarkable fact that, if the manufacturer adopts PCFM, profit of the supply chain will be less than that under classic “newsvendor” model, which, according to Proposition 5, is mainly because of the failure in meeting boundary conditions of interest rate.

7. Conclusions

The manufacturer will address the capital constraint during production and operation through financing in order to realize optimal production and maximize the profit. The manufacturer with capital constraint could finance through the retailer’s prepayment financing mode (RPFM) and the procurement contract financing mode (PCFM). Aiming at these two financing modes, in this paper, the optimal production and financing decision problems of the manufacturer are studied; meanwhile, under the RPFM, the optimal order quantity is studied based on the discount coefficient; at last, under both financing modes, we compare expected profits of the manufacturer, retailer, and the entire supply chain through the numerical simulation.

Through our analysis, the result shows that when the discount coefficient meets certain requirements, profits of the manufacturer, retailer, and the entire supply chain can all increase and will be generally superior to those under the PCFM. The optimal production volume of the manufacturer is greater than that with its own capital under the PCFM. In addition, due to the influence of interest rate and selection of initial simulation date, in this case, expected profits of the manufacturer and the entire supply chain are less than those with the manufacturer’s own capital and under classic “newsvendor” model.

In addition, our analytical and numerical results include some theoretical and managerial implications in terms of supply chain financial management and optimization. First, the retailer, manufacturer, and the entire supply chain are always more profitable and the manufacturer’s optimal production volume can be increased by financing. Hence, it proved that the financing service can create new value and impact on enterprise’s operational decision. Second, from the entire supply chain perspective, the bank’s loan interest rate plays a key role and influences the manufacturer’s financing decision-making and profit level. Moreover, the profit level under RPFM is higher than PCFM; it reveals why manufacturer prefers to select inner financing mode such as RPFM compared to external finance mode from a commercial bank.

Finally, there are some limitations and possible directions can be addressed in future research. First, our works mainly focus on the supply chain financing and optimal decision; however, how to use contracts to coordinate the capital-constrained supply chain under RPFM and PCFM will be another research problem in the future. Second, the commercial bank’s risk control and product residual value should be taken into account. Third, actually, under the condition of asymmetric information assumption, the retailer and manufacturer have game relationship. So, how to select the financing mode and make decision is needed to give the further discussion.

Notations

Unit retail price, wholesale price, production cost, and shortage cost of unit product, respectively
Price discount coefficient for prepayment, wherein ; ; and
The bank’s loan interest rate
The manufacturer’s initial budget (its own capital)
Prepayment of retailer
Manufacturer’s production volume with initial budget (its own capital)
The maximum production of manufacturer under prepayment
Loan amount from commercial bank under RPFM and PCFM
The manufacturer’s production volume, respectively, under “newsvendor” mode, RPFM, and PCFM
The manufacturer’s optimal production volume, respectively, under RPFM and PCFM
Profits of the manufacturer, retailer, and the entire supply chain with no capital constraint
Profits of the manufacturer, retailer, and the entire supply chain with its own capital
Profits of the manufacturer, retailer, and the entire supply chain under RPFM and PCFM
Random demand of market consumption. The probability density function and distribution function are and , respectively, wherein, satisfies the failure distribution IFDR characteristic of monotone increasing.

Competing Interests

The authors declare that there is no conflict of interests regarding the publication of this paper.

Acknowledgments

This work is supported by the National Natural Science Foundation of China (no. 71573072).