Abstract

This paper focuses on a stochastic differential game played between two insurance companies, a big one and a small one. In our model, the basic claim process is assumed to follow a Brownian motion with drift. Both of two insurance companies purchase the reinsurance, respectively. The big company has sufficient asset to invest in the risky asset which is described by the constant elasticity of variance (CEV) model and acquire new business like acting as a reinsurance company of other insurance companies, while the small company can invest in the risk-free asset and purchase reinsurance. The game studied here is zero-sum where there is a single exponential utility. The big company is trying to maximize the expected exponential utility of the terminal wealth to keep its advantage on surplus while simultaneously the small company is trying to minimize the same quantity to reduce its disadvantage. In this paper, we describe the Nash equilibrium of the game and prove a verification theorem for the exponential utility. By solving the corresponding Fleming-Bellman-Isaacs equations, we derive the optimal reinsurance and investment strategies. Furthermore, numerical examples are presented to show our results.

1. Introduction

Recently, most insurance companies manage their business by means of reinsurance and investment, which are effective way to spread risk and make profit. Therefore, these have inspired hundred researches. For instance, Schmidli [1], Promislow and Young [2], and Bai and Guo [3] investigated the optimal problems for an insurance company in the case of minimizing the ruin probability. Yang and Zhang [4], Wang [5], and Cao and Wan [6] studied the optimal reinsurance and investment problems of expected utility maximization. The latest researches on insurance and investment management problem can be referred to Yu et al. [7], Zhang et al. [8], Peng et al. [9], Yu et al. [10], Ruan et al. [11], Yu et al. [12], Huang et al. [13], Zeng et al. [14], Li et al. [15] and references therein.

However, most of the literature mentioned above only considered one insurance company, while there are many insurance companies in the market in reality and they compete with each other. Thus, two insurance companies, a big one and a small one, are focused on in this paper. This competition between the two insurance companies can be formulated as a stochastic differential game. In previous researches, Suijs et al. [16] showed that problems in non-life insurance and non-life reinsurance can be modeled as cooperative games. Zeng [17] discussed the competition between two companies and contrasted a single payoff function which depended on both insurance companies’ surplus processes. Taksar and Zeng [18] investigated stochastic differential games between two insurance companies who employed the reinsurance to reduce risk exposure. Some papers focus on the relative performance of two insurance companies under a nonzero sum stochastic differential game framework, such as Bensoussan et al. [19], Meng et al. [20], Pun and Wong [21], and Siu et al. [22]. However, some literatures related to stochastic differential games ignore the problem of investment in insurance companies. Nowadays, investment plays a significant role in the insurance business, especially for those big insurance companies who have enough ability to invest in the risky asset for more profits.

Another aspect worthy to be further explored is that the price processes of risky assets in most of literature about the optimal reinsurance and investment problems in frameworks of stochastic differential games are assumed to follow a geometric Brownian motion (GBM), which implies that the volatilities of risky assets are constant and deterministic. This is contrary to practice according to the empirical results. Therefore, many works proposed various stochastic volatility models, such as constant elasticity of variance (CEV) model (Cox and Ross [23]), Stein-Stein model (Stein and Stein [24]), Heston model (Heston [25]) and so on. Among these stochastic volatility models, the CEV model is a natural extension of the GBM model and has the ability of capturing the implied volatility skew and explaining the volatility smile. There is a great deal of literature documenting the CEV model in assets’ return for the optimal investment problem. For example, Gu et al. [26] considered the proportional reinsurance and investment problem for the diffusion risk model under the CEV model. Liang et al. [27] and Lin and Li [28] used the CEV model to study the proportional reinsurance and investment problem for an insurance company with the jump-diffusion risk model. Gu et al. [29] derived the excess-of-loss reinsurance and investment strategies with the risky asset’s price following the CEV model. Zheng et al. [30] considered the robust optimal portfolio and proportional reinsurance for an insurer under a CEV model.

As far as we know, there is few research investigating more than one insurance company under the CEV model. Therefore, in this paper, we consider a stochastic differential game played between two insurance companies, a big one and a small one. In our model, the basic claim processes is assumed to follow a Brownian motion with drift. Both of two insurance companies purchase the reinsurance, respectively. The big insurance company has more initial surplus than the small one, so the big company has sufficient asset to invest in the risky asset which is described by the CEV model and acquire new business like acting as a reinsurance company of other insurance companies, while the small company can only invest in the risk-free asset and purchase reinsurance. The game studied here is zero-sum where there is a single exponential utility. The big company is trying to maximize the expected exponential utility of the terminal wealth to keep its advantage on surplus while simultaneously the small company is trying to minimize the same quantity to reduce its disadvantage. Firstly, we describe the Nash equilibrium of the game and prove a verification theorem for the exponential utility. By solving the corresponding Fleming-Bellman-Isaacs equations, we derive the optimal reinsurance and investment strategies. Finally, numerical simulation are proposed to illustrate the impacts of the model parameters on the strategies. Through this paper, we find that (1) for such a game the small insurance company takes extreme or trivial strategy, i.e., the optimal reinsurance strategy of the small company is either 1 or 0; (2) the optimal reinsurance and investment strategies of the big company are independent of the wealth process ; (3) the effects of some model parameters on the big company’s optimal reinsurance strategy are related to the correlation coefficient between the big and small companies’ risk processes.

This paper proceeds as follows. In Section 2, we introduce the formulation of our model, describe the Nash equilibrium of the game, and prove a verification theorem for the exponential utility under the CEV model. Section 3 provides the optimal reinsurance and investment strategies of the big insurance company and the optimal reinsurance strategy of the small one in the stochastic differential game. In Section 4, numerical simulations are presented to illustrate our results. Section 5 concludes this paper.

2. Model Formulation

In this paper, we model the surplus process of the insurance company aswhere , are positive constants and is a standard Brownian motion. To reduce the risk exposure, the insurance company is allowed to purchase the reinsurance and represents the proportion of each claim paid by the insurance company. Assume is the rate at which the premiums are diverted to the reinsurance company. As usual, we have . Otherwise the insurance company will make a full reinsurance to receive a positive return with any risk. Considering the reinsurance, the surplus process of the insurance company becomes

In this paper, we consider a stochastic differential game played between two insurance companies, a big one and a small one. The big insurance company has more initial surplus than the small one, so the big company has sufficient asset to invest in the risky asset and acquire new business like acting as a reinsurance company of other insurance companies, while the small company can only invest in the risk-free asset and purchase reinsurance, i.e., the reinsurance strategies of the big and small companies and satisfy . The game considered here is zero-sum where there is a single exponential utility. The big company is trying to maximize the expected exponential utility of the terminal wealth to keep its advantage on surplus while simultaneously the small company is trying to minimize the same quantity to reduce its disadvantage. One company’s decision is assumed to be completely observed by its opponent.

Let be a complete probability space with filtration and two standard Brownian motions and , adapted to with , where is a fixed and finite time horizon. The surplus processes of the two insurance companies associated with the proportional reinsurance are given bywhere are constants, .

In this paper, the big insurance company is allowed to invest in a risk-free asset whose price process satisfiesand a risky asset whose price process is described by the CEV model (cf. Cox [31]):, where is the interest rate and , , and are the appreciation rate, the instantaneous volatility, and the elasticity parameter of the risky asset. is a standard Brownian motion independent of and . As usual, we assume that and satisfies the general condition . Meanwhile, the small one can invest in a risk-free asset to avoid risk. Strategies and are said to be admissible if they are progressively measurable and satisfy :where represents the amount invested in the risky asset by the big insurance company at time . Here is called the admissible set. Corresponding to an admissible strategy and the initial wealth , the wealth processes of the big and small insurance companies and are

Let ; then follows the following stochastic differential equation:where . Here, we usually assume , which describes that one of the two insurance companies is big, and the other is small. That is, this model is suitable for the case that is positive and we can distinguish the big and small companies easily. If is very small, we will choose the insurance company with larger initial wealth as the big one, and the other is the small one. If it is difficult to distinguish the big company and small company from the initial wealth, this framework may not be suitable.

Remark 1. If the elasticity parameter in equation (1), the CEV model reduces to the GBM model.
In this paper, we consider the exponential utility which is given bywhere . The exponential utility has the constant absolute risk aversion parameter , which plays an important role in insurance mathematics and actuarial practice.

Definition 1. Letthe strategy is said to achieve a Nash equilibrium or equivalently a saddle point for the game, if the following inequalities are satisfied. For all ,In addition, letdenote the lower and upper values of the game respectively. If , the value function of the game is given by .
In this paper, the goal of the big insurance company is to maximize the above expected exponential utility function while simultaneously the small one wants to minimize it. For convenience, we first provide some notations. Let be an open set and . Denote thatand define a variation operator: for any , letFor any given strategy by the small insurance company, let be the optimal expected exponential utility function of the big insurance company, i.e.,Then satisfies the following Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) equationSimilarly, let be the optimal expected exponential utility function of the small insurance company with any strategy given by the big insurance company, then satisfied another HJB equationDenoteAssume that a saddle point exits, then the game have a value function .
Let be the solution to the following equations:and substitute them into equations (16) and (17), respectively, we obtain the following equations:with the boundary condition .

Theorem 1 (Verification theorem). If there exists a continuously differential function andsatisfy equations (20) and (21) with the following moment properties

In addition, the parameters satisfy one of the following conditions:(a);(b), then is the optimal strategy and the optimal value function is .

Proof. See Appendix A.
The above theorem guarantees the solution to equations (20) and (21) is the value function for the game.

3. Solution to the Model

In this section, we solve the game under the expected exponential utility. The big company is trying to maximize the expected exponential utility of the terminal wealth to keep its advantage on surplus while the small company is trying to minimize the same quantity to reduce its disadvantage, i.e.,

Assume the Nash equilibrium exits and let satisfythen is the solution to equations (20) and (21) with the boundary condition and is the optimal value function according to Theorem 1.

The following theorem gives the optimal reinsurance and investment strategies of the big company and the reinsurance strategy of the small company in the game under the CEV model with the expected exponential utility.

Theorem 2. For the problem of maximizing the expected exponential utility for the big company while minimizing it for the small company under the CEV model, the optimal reinsurance and investment strategies are given as follows:(1)If and , the optimal reinsurance and investment strategies of the big company and the reinsurance strategy of the small company areThe value function is given by equation (B.21).(2)If , and , the optimal reinsurance strategies of the big and small companies arewhile the optimal investment strategy of the big company is the same as that in equation (11) and the value function is given in equation (B.25).(3)If , , and , the optimal reinsurance strategies of the big and small companies are the same as those in equation (26). The optimal investment strategy of the big company is expressed as that in equation (27) and the value function is given by equation (B.20).(4)If , , , and , the optimal reinsurance strategies of the big and small companies arewhile the optimal investment strategy of the big company is the same as that in equation (11) and the value function is given in equation (B.28).(5)If and , the optimal reinsurance strategies of the big and small companies areThe optimal investment strategy of the big company is expressed as that in equation (11) and the value function is given by equation (B.32).(6)If , and , the optimal reinsurance strategies of the big and small companies arewhile the optimal investment strategy of the big company is the same as that in equation (11) and the value function is given in equation (B.36).(7)If , , and , the optimal reinsurance strategies of the big and small companies areThe optimal investment strategy of the big company is expressed as that in equation (11) and the value function is given by equation (B.39).(8)If , , , , and , the optimal reinsurance strategies of the big and small companies are the same as those in equation (29), while the optimal investment strategy of the big company is the same as that in equation (27) and the value function is given in equation (B.39).(9)If , , , , and , the optimal reinsurance strategies of the big and small companies are

The optimal investment strategy of the big company is expressed as that in equation (11) and the value function is given by equation (B.42).

Proof. See Appendix B.

Remark 2. From Theorem 2 we conclude that the wealth has no influence on the optimal investment strategy. This can be explained by the risk tolerance of the exponential utility function. The risk tolerance is , which is independent of the wealth. Thus, the optimal strategy is independent of the wealth. In addition, the optimal reinsurance strategy of the big company is not related to the wealth as well and that of the small company is either 1 or 0, i.e., the small insurance company takes extreme or trivial strategy in this game.

Remark 3. In the case that the risky asset’s price follows the GBM model, the optimal strategy of the big insurance company isCompared with equation (34), we see that the optimal investment strategy under the CEV model can be decomposed into two parts. One iswhich is similar to the optimal strategy under the GBM model, but the volatility is stochastic. Thus, we call as the moving GBM strategy. The other one iswhich reflects the insurance company’s decision to hedge the volatility risk and we regard it as a correction factor.
The following corollary discusses the property of the correction factor.

Corollary 1. The correction factor is a monotone decreasing function with respect to time and satisfies

Proof. According to and , we derive . It implies that the correction factor is a monotone decreasing function with respect to time . Sinceand , we obtain inequality (37).

Corollary 1 shows that the correction factor advises the big insurance company to invest more wealth in the risky asset at the beginning of the investment horizon and steadily decrease the amounts as time goes on.

Remark 4. We find that the optimal investment strategy is independent of the optimal reinsurance strategies. The main reason is that in this model, we assume that the financial market is not affected by the insurance market, which is used in a great deal of existing literature, such as Bai and Guo [3], Gu et al. [26], Gu et al. [29], and so on.

4. Numerical Examples

In this section, we provide some numerical simulations to illustrate our results. Because the optimal reinsurance strategy of the small company is either 1 or 0, we analyze the optimal reinsurance and investment strategies of the big company here. Throughout numerical analysis, unless otherwise stated, the basic parameters are given by , , , , , , , , , , , , , , and .

4.1. Numerical Simulations of the Big Company’s Optimal Reinsurance Strategy

Figure 1 illustrates the influence of the risk averse coefficient on the optimal reinsurance strategy . The relationship between and is negative. This can be attributed to the fact that a larger means the big insurance company is a more risk-averse individual. With the increase of , the big company wants to purchase more reinsurance to avoid risk and undertake less risk itself.

Figure 2 shows the effect of on the optimal reinsurance strategy . As increases, the big insurance company will obtain more profit from investment in the risk-free asset. Therefore, it has more money to purchase the reinsurance and bear less risk itself, so decreases with .

Figure 3 indicates the impact of on the optimal reinsurance strategy . We can see that a greater yields a greater reinsurance strategy. This is because that as increases, the cost of reinsurance will become more expensive and the big insurance company prefers to maintain a stable revenue by purchasing less reinsurance and undertake more by itself.

As is shown in Figure 4, we find that is a decreasing function of . This can be explained by that implies the fluctuation of the big insurance company’s claim process. When increases, the insurance company wants to purchase more reinsurance while undertaking less risk by itself.

From Figure 5, we can see if , exerts a positive effect on the optimal reinsurance strategy and if , the effect is opposite. This can be attributed to that the fluctuations of the big and small companies’ claim processes are more serious with rising when . Therefore, the big company will take more risk, while when , the fluctuation of the big insurance company’s claim process is weaker with the volatility of the small company becoming stronger. So the big company will face less risk.

In Figure 6, we demonstrate the effect of the correlation coefficient between the big and small insurance companies’ risk processes on the optimal reinsurance strategy . We find that no matter is positive or negative, the higher is, the bigger is. This is because that for the big company, the more relevant the relationship between two companies is, the greater the influence of the small company on the big company is. So the big company has to undertake more risk with rising.

4.2. Numerical Simulations of the Big Insurance Company’s Optimal Investment Strategy

Figure 7(a) plots the evolution of the risky asset’s price over time under the CEV model. According to the change trend of the risky asset’s price, we plot the dynamic behaviors of the optimal investment strategy of the big insurance company in Figure 7(b) and we can see that the change trend of the optimal investment strategy is opposite to that of the risky asset’s price, which can be attributed to the expression of the CEV model. When the price of risky asset is high, the big company should be cautious to invest, for the reason that the higher the risky asset’s price is, the higher risk they will undertake.

In Figure 8(a), we find that the rate of the risky asset’s return exerts positive effect on the optimal investment strategy . This is consistent with intuition. As increases, the big company will obtain more from investment. Therefore, it will increase the amounts invested in the risky asset. As shown in Figure 8(b), the optimal investment strategy is a decreasing function of the interest rate . When the interest rate increases, the risk-free asset is more attractive. Then the big company will invest more in the risk-free asset and reduce investment in the risky asset.

Figure 9(a) indicates the impact of the risk averse coefficient on the optimal investment strategy . We see that exerts negative effect on , which means that the big company with the higher risk averse level will invest less in the risky asset to avoid risk. Figure 9(b) illustrates the effect of the elasticity coefficient on the optimal investment strategy . There is a negative relationship between and . This can be attributed to that a higher leads to a larger expected drop in volatility and increased probability of a large adverse movement in the risky asset’a price. Thus, the big company will invest less in the risky asset as increases to reduce the risk from the investment in the risky asset.

5. Conclusion

This paper considers a stochastic differential game played between two insurance companies, a big one and a small one. In our model, the basic claim process is assumed to follow a Brownian motion with drift. Both of two insurance companies purchase the reinsurance, respectively. The big insurance company has more initial surplus than the small one, so the big company has sufficient asset to invest in the risky asset which is described by the CEV model and acquire new business like acting as a reinsurance company of other insurance companies, while the small company can only invest in the risk-free asset and purchase reinsurance. The game studied here is zero-sum where there is a single exponential utility. The big company is trying to maximize the expected exponential utility of the terminal wealth to keep its advantage on surplus while simultaneously the small company is trying to minimize the same quantity to reduce its disadvantage. Firstly, we describe the Nash equilibrium of the game and prove a verification theorem for the exponential utility. By solving the corresponding Fleming-Bellman-Isaacs equations, we derive the optimal reinsurance and investment strategies. Finally, numerical simulation is proposed to illustrate the impacts of the model parameters on the strategies. Through this paper, we find that (1) for such a game, the small insurance company takes extreme or trivial strategy, i.e., the optimal reinsurance strategy of the small company is either 1 or 0; (2) the optimal reinsurance and investment strategies of the big company are independent of the wealth process ; (3) the effects of some model parameters on the big company’s optimal reinsurance strategy is related to the correlation coefficient between the big and small companies’ risk processes. In future work, we will consider more complex models, such as both two insurers can invest in the risky asset, or insurers will participate in the game.

Appendix

A. Proof of Theorem 1

Proof. By Itô’s formula, we haveTake a sequence of bounded open sets , , ,…, with , , and . For , let be the exiting time of from . Then when . Integrating from two sides of equation (A.1), we havethenSince the last five terms are square-integrable martingales with zero expectation, taking conditional expectation given on both sides of the above formula and taking equation (21) into account results thatBy virtue of Lemma B.1, , are uniformly integrable. It is easy to see that the equality holds for . Thus, we havei.e., . Similarly, we can proveHence, is a saddle point for the game by Definition 1 and according towe can deriveWhen , the inequality in the above formula becomes an equality, i.e., is the optimal value function.

B. Proof of Theorem 2

Proof. According to the exponential utility described by equation (9), we try to find the optimal value function in the following way:with the boundary condition given by . ThenFrom equation (B.2), we obtain , the infumum in equation (21) is reached at or . LetThe first-order maximizing conditions for the optimal reinsurance and investment strategies of the big company giveSubstituting , , and into equations (20) and (21) yieldsInserting derivatives in equation (B.2) into equation (B.5), we obtainIn the following section, we try to find the solutions to equations (20) and (21) in the following cases.

Case B.1. .
If , then . We have the optimal reinsurance strategies of the small and big company andEquation (B.7) shows that is equivalent to(1)If , we derive the optimal reinsurance strategies of the big and small companiesInputting equation (B.9) into equation (B.6) impliesEquation (B.10) can be decomposed into two equations by separating variablesTaking the boundary condition into account, the solution to equation (B.11) isIn order to solve equation (B.12), we defineand the boundary condition is . ThenSubstituting these derivatives into equation (B.15) yieldsWe try to find a solution to equation (B.16) with the following structure:and the boundary conditions are and . Plugging equation (B.17) into equation (B.15), we deriveBy matching coefficients, and satisfy the following equations:Considering the boundary conditions and , the solutions to equation (B.19) areThus, we obtainwhereand is given by equation (B.20).(2)If and , we have the optimal reinsurance strategies of the big and small companiesPutting equation (B.23) into equation (B.6), we deriveWe can solve equation (B.24) like Case B.1 (1) and getwherewith given in equation (B.20).(3)If , and , the optimal reinsurance strategies of the big and small companies are the same as those in equation (B.9) and the expression of is given by equation (B.21).(4)If , and , when , the optimal reinsurance strategies of the big and small companies are expressed as those in equation (B.23) and when , and are the same as those in equation (B.9), i.e.,By similar derivatives, noting that is continuous at and taking the boundary conditions into account, we obtainwhereand , and are given in equations (B.20) and (B.21).

Case B.2. and .
If and , then . The optimal reinsurance strategies of the big and small companies are as following:and equation (B.6) is simplified intoThus, satisfieswherewith given by equation (B.20).

Case B.3. and .
If and , we derive the optimal reinsurance strategy of the small companywhere . Let .(1)If , when , the optimal reinsurance strategies of the big and small companies are expressed as those in equation (B.9) and when , and are the same as those in equation (B.30), i.e.,Similarly, the expression of iswhereand , , are given in equations (B.20) and (B.33).(2)If and , when , the optimal reinsurance strategies of the big and small companies are expressed as those in equation (B.23) and when , and are the same as those in equation (B.30), i.e.,while iswherewith , and are given by equations (B.20) and (B.33).(3)If , and , the optimal reinsurance strategies of the big and small companies are expressed as those in equation (B.20) and is given in equation (B.36).(4)If , and , when , the optimal reinsurance strategies of the big and small companies are the same as those in equation (B.23), when , and are expressed as those in equation (B.9) and when , and are shown in equation (B.30), i.e.,Through the above derivatives, we obtainwherewith , , , , and are given by equations (B.20), (B.33), and (B.39).
To proof Theorem 1, we first introduce a lemma. For convenience, denote .

Lemma B.1. Take a sequence of bounded open sets , , ,…, with , and . Let be the exiting time of from . If one of the conditions (a) and (b) in Theorem 1 holds, then we have for .

Proof. We first denote for simplicity. Applying Itô’s formula, we haveSince are the optimal strategies of equations (20) and (21), . Putting the expressions of , , , , and into equation (B.44), we obtainThe solution to the above equation isAccording to the expression of the CEV model and Itô’s formula, we can deriveBy Zeng and Taksar [32], we know thatis martingales andwhen one of the conditions (a) and (b) in Theorem 1 is satisfied. According to the expression of , , and Novikov’s condition,are martingales. Taking expectation from both sides of equation (B.46) yieldsi.e., . So for .

Data Availability

The data used to support the findings of this study are included within the article.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare that they have no conflicts of interest.

Acknowledgments

This research was supported by the National Natural Science Foundation of China (Nos. 11801179, 71573110, 71771220, 11971172, 71701084), the “Chenguang Program”, Shanghai, China (No. 18CG26), the Fundamental Research Funds for the Central Universities (No. 2019ECNU-HWFW028), and the 111 Project, China (No. B14019).