Abstract

In this paper, we investigate a supply chain consisting of an OEM (i.e., original equipment manufacturer) and a CM (contract manufacturer), in which the OEM decides design effort level and marketing level, and the CM makes decision on product manufacturing effort level. We establish a three-dimensional discrete dynamic model with time delay. Firstly, the sufficient conditions for Neimark–Sacker bifurcation are obtained by using different combinations of decision delay periods as bifurcation parameters, and the effect of the adjustment speeds of decision variables on the system stability and impact of time delay on the system stability are discussed, respectively. Secondly, we perform numerical simulation of this model from the perspective of entropy theory. Finally, we propose two methods to control chaos. Results show that when the time delay or the adjustment speed of decision variable exceed a certain threshold, the system will be led into a chaotic state and the entropy of the system will increase. For alleviating the negative effects of chaotic systems, we introduce control parameters to make efficient control on the chaos. At the critical point, the critical value of the adjustment speed of design effort level (or marketing level) of OEM increases as the adjustment speed of the manufacturing effort level of CM decreases, and vice versa.

1. Introduction

By adding Huawei Technologies Co. Ltd. and its affiliates to the Bureau’s Entity List, the Bureau of Industry and Security (BIS) of the U.S. Department of Commerce has prohibited U.S companies from selling related technologies and products to Huawei, whose suppliers, such as Intel, Qualcomm, Xilinx, and Broadcom, will have to stop providing it with high-end chips in next moths. In order to reduce the potential disruption risk, Huawei has been implemented its “spare tire program” for more than a decade, in which its self-designed chips has partly been replaced with US high-end chips. By now, Huawei has independently developed a series of chips, and the Kirin series are the most representative ones. Since high-end chip manufacturing is a technology intensive, capital intensive, and extremely complex industry, Huawei’s self-designed high-end chip production has been outsourced to TSMC (Taiwan Semiconductor Manufacturing Company). Obviously, Huawei who is OEM focuses on R&D of Kirin series and marketing of the Huawei mobile phones including the chips, and TSMC is CM who is responsible for manufacturing of the chips. Huawei has been committed to its core business and enhanced its core competitiveness. In the second quarter of 2020, the market share of Huawei’s mobile phone rose to the first place in the world. Thus, it is of a substantial significance to investigate OEM supply chain with R&D and marketing.

The existing literature studies the coordination of the OEM supply chain by the perspective of operation research. Van et al. [1] examine the impact of four variants of vendor-managed inventory on channel cost and cost allocation in OEM supply chain comprised of a supplier and an OEM. Li et al. [2] explore a direct-sale closed-loop supply chain consisting of an OEM, a remanufacturer, and two advertising agents and analyze the impacts of the parameters of design and advertising on equilibrium and the profits of the parties. Shen et al. [3] investigate how design outsourcing affects the supply chain and analyze channel performance under an OEM strategy versus an ODM (i.e., Original Design Manufacturer) strategy. Niu et al. [4] investigate fashion supply chain including a supplier, a contract manufacturer, and a fashion brand and discuss the fashion brand’s profit performances under OEM strategy or ODM strategy. Kong and Li [5] examine the elasticity operation and promotion strategy for OEM supply chain and propose a deep learning mechanism to improve the flexibility of the channel. If the OEM supply chain is explored from entropy theory perspective, can more interesting conclusions be made?

In recent years, there have been the growing concerns on R&D in the supply chains. Huang et al. [6] present a collaborative R&D model based on costumers’ selection behavior and analyze the joint decisions on R&D and pricing in a supply chain. Stefano and Montes-Sancho [7] explore how the interaction between dyadic and network relationships can contribute to increase the success of environmental R&D cooperation. Yoo and Seo [8] propose six models on three-stage supply chain consisting of a R&D firm, a manufacturer, and a retailer and examine the effect of supply chain structure and players’ power dynamics on R&D decision and market performances in a supply chain. Taleizadeh and Moshtagh [9] propose a consignment stock scheme for a closed-loop supply chain with imperfect manufacturing processes, lost sales, and quality dependent on return. Taleizadeh and Noori-daryan [10] propose pricing, manufacturing, and inventory policies for raw material in a three-level supply chain. Zhang et al. [11] present an implementation scheme of manufacturers considering remanufacturable design level under the multiperiod decision-making environment. Ma et al. [12] investigate a two-stage supply chain including two competitive manufacturers and one retailer and illustrate the optimal green manufacturing level and pricing.

Marketing is also an interesting aspect of supply chain research. Kort et al. [13] discuss pricing decisions in dual-channel supply chain in the presence of optional contingent products. Yaghin [14] investigates a production planning problem in dyadic supply chain with multiperiod, multiproduct, multisite, and multi-sales channels. Golgeci and Kuivalainen [15] discuss the role of absorptive capacity and marketing-supply chain management alignment and analyze the potential impact of social capital on supply chain resilience. Chernonog [16] investigates inventory and marketing policies in a supply chain with a perishable product.

Some researchers analyze the dynamic characteristics of the supply chain by using the entropy theory. Elsadany and Awad [17] focus on the difference between price and quantity competition in a mixed duopoly game and address the behavior of a duopolistic Bertrand competition market with environmental taxes. Ma et al. [18] examine a multichannel supply chain and discuss the complexity and bullwhip effect of each channel. Mondal [19] analyzes the stationary solutions of the proposed model and their stability conditions by using Routh–Hurwitz criteria. Yang et al. [20] propose the event trigger control protocol for fractional order nonlinear multiagent supply chain finance. Li et al. [21] explore a low-carbon dual-channel supply chain and discuss the effects of different parameter values on the price stability and utility of the supply chain system. In addition, Saravanakumar et al. [22] discuss the results of dissipative control for kinds of switched neutral time-delayed systems and obtain the sufficient conditions for boundedness. Saravanakumar et al. [23] use Lyapunov technique and LIM approach to investigate the problems of robust dissipative control for kinds of discrete-time systems.

What are the dynamic characteristics of an OEM supply chain with R&D and marketing from perspective of entropy theory? This will be an interesting and challenging subject. So far, the OEM supply chain has been applied by many multinational high-tech companies, and many scholars have an increasing interest in the OEM supply chain. Since most of decision makers are risk-averse and egocentric, it is more interesting to investigate the dynamic characteristics of an OEM supply chain with the time delay. In this paper, we investigate an OEM supply chain consisting of an OEM and a CM, in which OEM first decides the design effort level and marketing level, and then CM makes decision on the manufacturing effort level of the product. We discuss the effect of the time delay of three decision variables (i.e., design effort level , marketing level , and manufacturing effort level ) on the OEM supply chain. We obtain the conditions for the time delay to induce the bifurcation of the system through theoretical proofs and numerical simulation. In addition, we analyze the conditions of the system’s period-doubling bifurcation induced by the adjustment speed of the decision variables.

Compared with the existing classical research studies on coordination of OEM supply chains from operation management perspective, in which most of distributors and retailers are completely rational. The proposed method in this paper is used to analyze the chaotic behavior of OEM supply chain with time delay from entropy theory perspective, in which the distributor and the retailer are characteristic of bounded rationality.

The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. Description and assumption of the problem are presented in Section 2. The model is established in Section 3, and Section 4 discusses the dynamic characteristics of the problem. Section 5 addresses the dynamic characteristics of the problem by numerical simulation. Section 6 proposes two methods to control chaos. Section 7 concludes the paper with discussion of the possible future research.

2. Description and Assumption of the Problem

2.1. Model Construction and Assumptions

We investigate an OEM supply chain with R&D efforts including design effort level of the OEM and manufacturing effort level of the CM. The OEM and CM are responsible for the entire lifecycle of their products for consumers, from conception, through development and eventually to marketing. The OEM determines the design effort level and marketing level of the products, and manufacturing of the products is outsourced to the CM who decides the manufacturing effort level .

The main assumptions of this paper are made as follows:(i)The CM and the OEM are bounded rational.(ii)One-time investment is only taken into account in this paper. When the design effort level, marketing level, and manufacturing effort level are , , and respectively, the OEM and CM will have to incur the one-time investment cost , , and , where , , are the cost coefficient [24].(iii)R & D effort includes design effort level of the OEM and manufacturing effort level of the CM.(iv)The OEM and the CM are risk-averse, so they adopt the delayed decision policy.

2.2. Symbolic Description

The meanings of , and are described concisely in Table 1.

Based on the existing literature [25], the functional form of market demand can be written as follows:where expresses the market demand scale unaffected by other market factors, describes the consumers’ sensitivity to R&D efforts, and OEM’s marketing level is denoted by . and represent manufacturing effort level of CM and design effort level of OEM, respectively.

3. Multiperiod Decision-Making Game Model with Time Delay

The profit functions of the OEM and the CM can be written as follows:

As mentioned above, the decision variable of CM is manufacturing effort level and the decision variables of OEM are design effort level and marketing level . The marginal profit functions can be written as follows:

Due to the complexity of the market, the OEM or the CM cannot acquaint entirely the complete information of the other decision maker and predict accurately the true information of the market. Therefore, the CM and the OEM are bounded rational. The decisions in the current period are dependent on the corresponding decisions in the last period and its marginal profit. The decisions in period t +1 under bounded rational hypothesis are the corresponding decisions in period t plus the variations of decisions at period t [26]:where stand for the adjustment speed of marketing level , manufacturing effort level , and design effort level , respectively. When the marginal profit of some decision variable is positive (or negative) in period t, the corresponding decision variables will increase (or decrease) in period t +1.

Because the OEM and the CM are risk-averse, so they adopt the delayed decision policy. Therefore, the three-dimensional discrete dynamic model with time delay can be proposed, which is referred to as model I:

4. Existence and Local Stability of Neimark–Sacker Bifurcation

4.1. Positive Equilibrium Points and Characteristic Equation of Model I

Based on repeated game theory, after the decision variables’ continuous adjustment for some periods, model I can achieve an equilibrium state when the OEM (or the CM) may not improve his profit by first changing his own decision. The equilibrium points of the model I are :

The stability of each equilibrium point can be proved by solving its Jacobian matrix. Only if all the eigenvalues of its Jacobian matrix are less than 1, this equilibrium point is stable. Otherwise, it is unstable. The Jacobian matrix of model I can be written as follows:where

First, judge the Jacobian matrix of equilibrium point :

Obviously, all eigenvalues of are greater than 1, so is an unstable equilibrium point. Similarly, it can be proved that only is a locally stable equilibrium point, and the others are unstable.

Let and , then let , and . For simplicity, is transformed into the point (0, 0, 0). First-order Taylor expansion of equation (5) at the equilibrium point is given:where

Next, the characteristic determinant of model I can be written as follows:And then, the characteristic polynomial of model I can be obtained:where

4.2. , Sufficient Conditions for Local Stability at Equilibrium Point

When , equation (13) can be simplified as follows:

Let , according to Routh–Hurwitz criterion, if , and , the equilibrium point is locally asymptotically stable.

4.3. , Sufficient Conditions for Local Stability at Equilibrium Point

Let , and multiply both sides by ; then,

Assuming that is the root of equation (16), thenwhere

In terms of equation (17), we havewhere

Define

We assume that has at least one positive real root. Without loss of generality, we assume that has n positive roots which are denoted by . From equation (17), we have

Denote

Differentiating both sides of equation (16) with regard to and substituting into the obtained expression, then we can obtainwhere

If condition holds, model I satisfies the condition of the occurrence for Neimark–Sacker bifurcation, so the following conclusions can be drawn.

Theorem 1. For model I, if conditions hold, the equilibrium point is asymptotically stable for ; when , model I undergoes a Neimark–Sacker bifurcation at equilibrium point ; model I is unstable at equilibrium point when .

5. Numerical Simulation

In this section, we present some simulations to verify our conclusion. On the premise of satisfying the conditions listed in this paper, we take the parameter values as follows: . We use the largest Lyapunov exponent and entropy to illustrate the features of the dynamic system. The principle of the largest Lyapunov exponent is that when exponent value is less than zero the system is stable, when exponent value is greater than zero, the system is unstable. According to the entropy theory, the more orderly the system, the lower its information entropy; conversely, the more chaotic the system, the higher its information entropy. Therefore, information entropy can also be said to be a measure of the degree of ordering of the system. When the entropy value of the system is zero, the system is so enough informative as to alleviate uncertainty, and it is in a stable state. By contrast, when the entropy value of system is more than zero, uncertainty of the system increases, and the system even goes into chaos. Thus, when the system is in a chaotic state, the decision makers have to collect more additional information to alleviate uncertainty.

5.1. Bifurcation Diagram Caused by Delay

By numerical simulation, . The bifurcation diagram of the system stability with respect to is shown in Figure 1.

As can be seen from Figure 1(a), when , equilibrium point is asymptotically stable; when , model I is in a chaotic state and gradually produces Neimark–Sacker bifurcation from the stable state with the increase of .

From Figure 1(a), it can be seen that when the time delay exceed a certain range, model I produces bifurcation or goes into chaos, which means that overdelayed decision-making will make the decision makers lose the best decision-making opportunity. Therefore, the OEM and the CM should make decisions in time to prevent the system from entering a chaos state. The entropy of model I with respect to is shown in Figure 1(b). When , the entropy of model I is equal to 0, and model I is in a stable state at this time; when , the entropy of model I continues increasing, and model I is in a chaotic state at this time. Comparing Figure 1(a) with Figure 1(b), it can be seen that the entropy of the system is increasing rapidly when bifurcation occurs and gets in chaos. Similarly, comparing Figure 1(a) with Figure 1(c), when bifurcation occurs and the system gets in chaos, the results of the largest Lyapunov exponent are consistent with that of bifurcation diagram, as shown in Figure 1(a).

5.2. Bifurcation Diagram Caused by Adjustment Speed of Decision

Ceteris paribus, when , the influence of time delay on the stability of the system can be eliminated. Then, we study the influence of adjustment speed on the stability by using 2D bifurcation diagram. First of all, when is fixed at 0.95, is fixed at 0.85, and changes from 0 to 0.5, we discuss the effect of the adjustment speed of marketing level on the stability of model I. From Figure 2(a), if increases from 0 to 0.195, model I is in a stable state, that is, the design effort level , marketing level , and manufacturing effort level stay at the equilibrium solution ; if , the first bifurcation of the system occurs and the system turns into stable cycles of period 2, which means that the design effort level , marketing level , and manufacturing effort level have two possible values; with the further increase of , the design effort level , marketing level , and manufacturing effort level become chaotic, that is, each decision variable has a lot of possible values.

Numerical simulations made by the largest Lyapunov exponent and entropy are shown in Figures 2(c) and 2(d). When , the largest Lyapunov exponent reaches the first zero, and model I shows the bifurcation phenomenon; when the largest Lyapunov exponent is more than zero, model I goes into chaos. Similarly, when , the entropy of model I is equal to 0, and model I is in a stable state; when , the entropy of model I continues to increase, period-doubling bifurcation occurs, and model I falls into chaos finally.

Compared with Figure 2(a), Figure 2(b) shows the change of the stability of model I with when reduces to 0.78. Obviously, with the decrease of adjustment speed of the CM’s manufacturing effort level , the critical point of the stability of model I is shifted to the right, that is, as the adjustment speed of manufacturing effort level decreases, the critical value of adjustment speed of marketing level increases.

Let , and varies from 0 to 0.5, and we analyze the effect of the adjustment speed of manufacturing level on the stability of model I. (i) When increases from 0 to 0.15, the design effort level , marketing level , and manufacturing effort level are fixed at the equilibrium point in Figure 3(a), the largest Lyapunov exponent is less than zero in Figure 3(c), the entropy is equal to zero in Figure 3(d), and model I is in a stable state in the three Figures above. (ii) When continues increasing to 0.15, the first bifurcation occurs in Figure 3(a), and model I turns into stable cycles of period 2, which means that each decision variable has two possible values; the largest Lyapunov exponent is equal to zero in Figure 3(c), and the entropy of the system is more than zero in Figure 3(d), so the system becomes chaotic in Figures 3(c) and 3(d). (iii)With the increase of , model I goes into chaos, which means that the design effort level , the marketing level , or the manufacturing effort level has a lot of possible values in Figures 3(a)3(c).

Comparing Figure 3(a) with Figure 3(b), we find that, with decrease of the adjustment speed of the design effort level , the critical point of the stability is shifted to the right, that is, with decrease of the adjustment speed of the design effort level , the critical value of adjustment speed of the manufacturing effort level increases.

Let , and varies from 0 to 0.5, we analyze the effect of the adjustment speed of design effort level on the stability of model I. (i)When increases from 0 to 0.136, the design effort level , marketing level , and manufacturing level stay at the equilibrium point in Figure 4(a), and the largest Lyapunov exponent is less than zero in Figure 4(c), the entropy is equal to zero in Figure 4(d), and model I is in a stable state in the three Figures above. (ii) When continues increasing to 0.136, the first bifurcation occurs in Figure 4(a), and model I turns into stable cycles of period 2, which means that each decision variable has two possible values; the largest Lyapunov exponent is equal to zero in Figure 4(c), and the entropy of the system is more than zero in Figure 4(d), so the system becomes chaotic in Figures 4(c) and 4(d). (iii) With further increase of , model I goes into chaos, which means that each of three decision variables has a lot of possible values in Figures 4(a)4(c).

Comparing Figure 4(a) with Figure 4(b), a conclusion can be made that, with decrease of the adjustment speed of the manufacturing effort level , the critical point of the stability is shifted to the right. That is, with decrease of the adjustment speed of the manufacturing effort level , the critical value of adjustment speed of the design effort level increases.

Chaotic attractor is an important tool to characterize the chaotic state. When the system goes into a chaotic state, the structure of the chaotic attractor will be more complicated. Let and . The system is in a chaotic state and Figure 5 illustrates the chaotic attractors.

From Figures 15, it can be seen that the faster the adjustment of the decision variables increases, the earlier the system gets into chaos. According to the entropy theory, when the system is chaotic, the entropy is high and the decision variables have a lot of possible values, which also causes that the decision maker make more effort to acquire useful information for alleviating uncertainty. Furthermore, the OEM and the CM should deliberate for decision time delay and the adjustment speed of the decision variables.

6. Chaos Control

From the previous discussion, both the time delay and the adjustment speed of the decision variables may cause the system to bifurcate, and even enter a chaotic state, which will always be harmful to make appropriate decision in a supply chain. Therefore, we try to control the chaos by the adjustment parameter control method and variable feedback control method, respectively. Let , and . As mentioned above, when other parameters keep fixed, model I is in a chaotic state.

6.1. Adjustment Parameter Control Method

In the adjustment parameter control method, the OEM and the CM cooperate with each other by jointly taking some measures to control the system chaos. Signing a contract is a common internal control measure.

The original model:

After being controlled by parameter adjustment, the controlled model can be written as [27]

Figure 6 illustrates that the chaos can be delayed or eliminated with a proper value of . When , the system is in the chaotic state. With the increasing of , model I gets rid of chaos and goes into the stable state.

6.2. Variable Feedback Control Method

The main principle of the variable feedback control method is to use equation variables as control signals to eliminate chaos, which can be regarded as the regulation issued by the government for controlling the adjustment speeds of decision variables in the market. Compared with other control methods, this method has the advantage of only designing a simple controller. The controlled system can be expressed as follows [28]:

The evolution process of model I with respect to is shown as Figure 7. When , the system is in the chaotic state; when , the system comes to a stable state and remains stable throughout, which indicates that the chaos of the system has been controlled effectively by some external intervention measures.

Figures 6 and 7 address the variation of model I under the adjustment parameter control and the variable feedback control, respectively. It is obvious that the control system in Figure 7 enters the stable state earlier than that in Figure 6. The control effect of the variable feedback control method is more efficient than that of the adjustment parameter control method because of the serious free riding in a supply chain. For controlling chaos may come with additional costs, the OEM and the CM have no incentive to cooperate with each other for controlling the system chaos. An unstable OEM supply chain can be efficiently transformed into a stable and orderly system through a relevant compulsory regulation issued by the government.

7. Conclusion

In this paper, we investigate a time delay supply chain including an OEM and a CM. The OEM decides product design effort level and marketing level , and the CM makes decision on product manufacturing effort level . Firstly, the mathematical description of the problem is formulated by three-dimensional discrete dynamic equations. Secondly, the positive equilibrium points and characteristic equation are discussed. The sufficient conditions for local stability at equilibrium point are analyzed. In addition, the effects of the adjustment speeds of decision variable on the decision variables are illustrated by using 2D bifurcation diagram, entropy, and chaotic attractor, respectively. Finally, the chaotic system can be transformed into the stable state by using the parameter control method and variable feedback control method, respectively. Several interesting conclusions are drawn as follows:

(1) The equilibrium point of the system is locally asymptotically stable when the value of the time delay is less than the critical value ; however, if the value of time delay is more than the critical value , the system loses its stability and undergoes a Neimark–Sacker bifurcation. (2) If the adjustment speed of decision variable of the OEM or the CM increases to some threshold, the system will go into the chaotic state and the entropy of the system will increase. According to the entropy theory, when the entropy value of the system is low, the system is so enough informative as to alleviate uncertainty, and it is in a stable state. By contrast, when the entropy value of the system is high, uncertainty of the system increases and system even go into chaos. Thus, when the system is in a chaotic state, the decision makers have to collect more additional information to alleviate uncertainty. (3) At the critical point, as the adjustment speed of manufacturing effort level of CM decreases, the critical value of the adjustment speed of design effort level (or marketing level) of OEM increase, and vice versa. For example, ceteris paribus, the critical value of increases as decreases; the critical value of increases as decreases. (4) When the system is in a chaotic state, the internal control method and external control method can be generally used to eliminate chaos. For all parties in supply chain are so egoistic that they have difficulty in making a cooperation, the external control method can be more efficient than internal control method.

In the future research, we will take into account the impact of behavior factors on the system, such as altruistic preference and fairness concerns. In addition, it is an interesting subject to consider the fractional order equation as the form of demand function in an OEM supply chain.

Data Availability

The data used to support the findings of this study are available from the corresponding author upon request.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflicts of interest.

Acknowledgments

The research was supported by the Key Project of Natural Science Research of Universities in Anhui Province (KJ2019A0662) and Graduate Research and Innovation Fund of Anhui University of Finance and Economics (ACYC2019205).