Abstract

More and more contract manufacturers have started to establish their own brands besides providing manufacturing service for retailers who operate exclusive well-known brands. This paper studies the encroachment strategy of a contract manufacturer in a supply chain and the impact of fairness concern. Four scenarios are investigated by building game models: no fairness concern, the retailer’s fairness concern, the contract manufacturer’s fairness concern, and both members’ fairness concern. The results show that when there is no fairness concern, the contract manufacturer always has motivation to encroach. However, when there exists fairness concern, only when the reservation price is sufficiently high, the contract manufacturer will encroach. Fairness concern has certain strength to stop the contract manufacturer’s encroachment. When the reservation price is sufficiently low, the encroachment of the contract manufacturer benefits the retailer, or else it will harm the benefit of the retailer. The effect of fairness concern on profit margin and wholesale price decisions is opposite under different encroachment strategies. However, the fairness concern has no impact on the retail price of the private brand. Under encroachment strategy, contract manufacturer’s or both members’ fairness concerns have positive effect on the retailer’s profit in certain conditions. However, the fairness concern always decreases the contract manufacturer’s profit no matter what the form it is. Numerical examples show that it is best for the supply chain that both members have fairness concern under no encroachment. However, when the contract manufacturer has a private brand, it is best for the supply chain that no one has fairness concern when the advantageous inequity concern parameter is sufficiently low. When the advantageous inequity concern parameter is sufficiently high, it is best for the supply chain that both members have fairness concern.

1. Introduction

In past decades, outsourcing has played an important role in world economy [13]. There are a lot of contract manufacturers who provide production services for well-known brands in China. The rapid development of e-commerce provides contract manufacturers with opportunities to sell directly to consumers. Many contract manufacturers have started to establish their own brands [4], which are called private brand [5], factory brand [6], or self-branded product [7]. For example, Sumvim has been the largest household textile company in China according to the value of export since 1999. In recent years, the company has established two private brands. One is Furi and the other is Jieyu, which are mainly sold in the domestic market in China. Recently, Sumvim has been cooperating with Pinduoduo Inc. (PDD) to promote her private brands while the latter has been one of the largest online group discounters in China. Actually, PDD launched the “New Brand Plan” at the end of 2018 aiming to hep 1000 manufacturers in China to establish their private brands. There are a lot of contract manufacturers adopting the same strategy as Sumvim, such as Guangdong Songfa Ceramics Co., Ltd., Zhejiang Sanhe Kitchenware Co., Ltd., and so on. However, there are still some manufacturers choosing not to build private brands, such as Crystal International Group Limited, who is a giant manufacturer of Uniqlo, H&M, and Levi’s [5]. This observation motivates us to study the encroachment strategy of contract manufacturers: encroachment or no encroachment. In what condition the contract manufacturer chooses to encroach and in what condition the manufacturer chooses not to encroach? What is the impact of encroachment on member’s profit?

In making decision, people can be influenced by many factors. One important factor is fairness concern, which can be modelled as inequity aversion that people will sacrifice certain material payoff to achieve fairness [8]. Thus, an interesting question arises: whether fairness concern influences contract manufacturer’s encroachment strategy? Different members may have different fairness concern [9, 10]. Thus, this paper studies four different scenarios of fairness concern: (1) the retailer’ fairness concern (scenario A); (2) the contract manufacturer’ fairness concern (scenario B); (3) both the manufacturer and the retailer’s fairness concern (scenario C); and (4) no fairness concern (scenario N). The main questions this paper is trying to answer are as follows.(1)What is the encroachment strategy of the contract manufacturer under different fairness concerns?(2)What is the impact of encroachment on the profits of members?(3)How do different fairness concerns impact the encroachment strategy of the contract manufacturer?(4)How do different fairness concerns affect the decisions and profits of the contract manufacturer, the retailer, and the whole supply chain under two encroachment strategies?

This paper contributes to the literature of supply chain encroachment. Encroachment in supply chain has been a hot issue. The most studied encroachment in supply chain is the retailer’s private label/store brand [1115] and manufacturer’s dual-channel strategy [1619]. However, the contract manufacturer’s encroachment has gained little attention. Several papers investigate the contract manufacturer’s encroachment strategy. Shi [7] studied the quality decisions and the contract manufacturer’s encroachment strategy under different channel leadership structures. The result shows that when the quality investment cost factor is sufficiently low, the contract manufacturer will never encroach. Sometimes, the encroachment of the contract manufacturer harms the benefit of the retailer. Cui [4] studied the free riding problem of quality considering the encroachment of the contract manufacturer. Chen et al. [5] explored the distribution channel decision of a contract manufacturer who operates a factory brand. However, to the best knowledge of the author, no paper has studied the impact of fairness concern on the encroachment strategy of contract manufacturer; this paper fills the gap; especially four different fairness concern scenarios are considered. Referring to retailer’s encroachment, some results show that it will be a threat to the other member in the supply chain [20, 21], whereas in some condition, the other member will benefit from the encroachment of the retailer [22, 23]. Similarly, there are two different point of views about the manufacturer’s dual-channel strategy. Some results show that adding a direct channel can harm the profit of the retailer; however, some studies show that it can be beneficial for the retailer in some instances [1618]. This paper also finds that the contract manufacturer’s encroachment is not always harmful to the other member. When the reservation price is sufficiently low, it will benefit the retailer, or else it will harm the retailer’s profit. Li et al., [24] studied the impact of retailer’s fairness concern on the supplier’s encroachment. They find that when the retailer has fairness concern, the supplier has more flexibility to encroach and the retailer has more possibility to benefit from supplier encroachment. They also find that retailer’s fairness concern can benefit the whole supply chain. Different from them, this paper considers not only the retailer’s fairness concerns but also other two fairness concern scenarios. This paper finds that the retailer’s fairness concern decreases the retailer’s profit, whereas the contract manufacturer’s fairness concern increases the retailer’s profit. When both members have fairness concern, the impact on the retailer’s profit can be negative or positive. The retailer’s fairness concern improves the profit of the whole supply chain under no encroachment, whereas it decreases the profit of the whole supply chain under encroachment.

2. Literature Review

This paper relates to contract manufacturer’s encroachment and fairness concern. This section will review related literature.

2.1. Contract Manufacturer’s Encroachment

Supply chain encroachment is a very common phenomena in industry. Traditionally, there are two kinds of supply chain encroachment which are studied substantially. One is retailer’s private brand/private label [1115]. Giant retailers such as Walmart, Amazon, and JD.com all have private brands. They sell products for national manufacturers while at the same time sell products on their own brands in the same categories. Another type is manufacturer’s direct channel/dual-channel strategy [1619]. The manufacturer opens a direct channel selling the same product online or similar product under the same brand name, such as Apple and HP. However, the contract manufacturer’s encroachment to build private brands/factory brands is rarely seen in literature. This research studies the encroachment strategy of the contract manufacturer: encroachment or no encroachment. Contract manufacturer’s encroachment has gained little attention in the past. However, in recent years, there are more and more papers starting to pay attention to this issue [47, 25]. Niu et al. [6] studied the impact of pricing sequence on the supply chain where the contract manufacturer owns a self-branded product besides providing manufacturing service to the client. Cui [4] combined the contract manufacturer’s encroachment with quality decision where the contract manufacturer is a free rider who can imitate the client’s product quality. Chen et al. [5] considered that a contract manufacturer introduces own-label product and competes with the client in the market. This own-label product is called factory brand in their paper. They mainly study the distribution problem of the factory brand. A three-level supply chain is considered. Shi [7] investigated the contract manufacturer’s encroachment strategy considering quality and pricing decisions. Literature [25] extends literature [7] and considers the advertising effort. However, none of existing research has considered the fairness concern problem of members in the supply chain. This paper fills the gap. In above literature, the client who owns a well-known brand in the market is called original equipment manufacturer (OEM). However, in practice, the contract manufacturer who provides the manufacturing service is also called OEM. Thus, in order to avoid the confusion, this paper uses “retailer” to denote the client of the contract manufacturer. The retailer owns an existing well-known brand and focuses on the promotion of the brand. The contract manufacturer provides production for the retailer. Now the contract manufacturer has two strategies to choose from: encroachment or no encroachment.

2.2. Fairness Concern

There are mainly two kinds of fairness concerns studied in literature. One is peer-induced fairness concern and the other is distributional fairness concern. Peer-induced fairness considers the fairness in the horizontal level. For example, two retailers sell the products for a manufacturer. The retailer’s fairness concerns about the other retailer is called peer-induced fairness. The retailer’s fairness concerns about the manufacturer is called distributional fairness [9]. This paper only considers distributional fairness.

Fairness concern has been studied substantially in supply chain literature [10, 2632]. Guan et al. [26] studied the channel coordination under Nash bargaining fairness concerns. Both quality improvement of the manufacturer and the advertising effort of the retailer are considered. Adhikari and Bisi [10] studied the impact of fairness concern on the greening and the pricing decisions in a green apparel supply chain. They considered two scenarios: the apparel retailer is fairness-concerned, whereas the apparel manufacturer is fairness-neutral and vice versa. They used Nash bargaining model to incorporate the fairness concern. Their results show that the greening quality and the retailer price are not affected by the retailer’s fairness concern. However, it has a decreasing effect on the wholesale price under greening cost sharing contract. In profit sharing contract, the retailer’s fairness concern lowers the greening quality, wholesale price, and the retail price, whereas the manufacturer’s fairness concern does not have any impact on the decisions. Pan et al. [27] investigated a supply chain consisting of a dominant retailer and two manufacturers. The effects of fairness concern on pricing, profitability, and utility of supply chain members are discussed. Both peer-induced fairness concern and distributional fairness concern are considered. Sharma et al. [31] combined option contract with fairness concern by using Nash bargaining solution. Liu and Chen [33] studied a supply chain consisting of a dominated manufacturer and a newsvendor retailer. Each one of them can be inequity-averse. They studied the green level, wholesale price, and ordering quality of members. Li et al. [34] investigated a two-echelon supply chain containing a fairness-neutral manufacturer and a fairness-concerned retailer considering carbon emission reduction. However, they did not consider other fairness concern situations and supply chain encroachment.

Referring to combination of supply chain encroachment with fairness concern, there are very few studies. Huang and Feng [35] studied the retailer’s encroachment strategy considering the manufacturer’s fairness concern. For dual-channel setting where the manufacturer builds a direct channel selling the same product with traditional retail channel, there are a lot of studies considering the fairness concern problem. Li and Li [36] considered a dual-channel supply chain where a manufacturer adds a direct channel. The retailer has fairness concern and adds value-added service to the product. They find that channel efficiency falls with retailer’s fairness concerns. Zhen et al. [9] studied a dual-supply chain in which a manufacturer produces and sells products through direct online channel and a retailer sells directly to consumers through online and offline channels. They considered four scenarios: no fairness concern, the retailer’s fairness concern, the manufacturer’ fairness concern, and both the manufacturer and the retailer have fairness concern. When referring to the contract manufacturer’s encroachment, to the best knowledge of the author, there is no research about fairness concern problem. This paper contributes to literature by filling this gap.

2.3. Research Gap

This section discusses contribution to the existing literature. Comparison between this paper with relevant papers is shown in Table 1. There are several substantial contributions in this study. Firstly, there is substantial research on retailer’s private brand (private-labelled products) and manufacturer’s dual-channel strategy. However, there is little attention on the private brand strategy of the contract manufacturer who establishes a new brand selling directly to the end-consumer market besides providing manufacturing service for the retailer. Existing literature on contract manufacturer has not considered the fairness concern. This paper combines the contract manufacturer’s encroachment strategy and fairness concern for the first time. Secondly, this paper compares the decisions and profit of the retailer and the contract manufacturer under four different member’s fairness concerns: no fairness concern, retailer’s fairness concern, contract manufacturer’s fairness concern, and both members’ fairness concern. Thirdly, this paper studies the impact of fairness concern on the encroachment strategy of the contract manufacturer.

3. Basic Model

Consider a supply chain consisting of a contract manufacturer and a well-known brand owner. In this paper, the brand owner is called as “retailer,” such as IKEA, Nike, and Adidas. The contract manufacturer produces products for the retailer in OEM/ODM mode. That is, it is the retailer who sells the products to the end market. The contract manufacturer has no end-market brand. It is assumed that the retailer is the leader who has a stronger bargaining power than the contract manufacturer. The retailer moves first and demands a profit margin , and then the contract manufacturer decides wholesale price . The retail price in end-consumer market is . Now the contract manufacturer is considering whether to establish a private brand of her own. Usually, the contract manufacturer will introduce a brand in the same category with the retailer’s brand to fully utilize her production line. Thus, the private brand may compete with the retailer’s existing brand in the consumer market. Usually, it is the retailer who gains most profit from the supply chain. When the supply chain structure experiences change, the profit of the supply chain is distributed in another way. Both members may rethink their decisions. In this paper, we incorporate fairness concern to their decisions to explore the impact of fairness concern on their decisions. This paper will study four different scenarios: neither the retailer nor the contract manufacturer has fairness concern (N), the retailer has fairness concern (A), the contract manufacturer has fairness concern (B), or both have fairness concern (C).

3.1. Demand Function

When the contract manufacturer encroaches, there are two brands in the market. One is the retailer’s existing brand and the other is the contract manufacturer’s private brand. According to the Hotelling model [38], the consumer market is conceptualized as a straight line. The retailer’s existing brand and contract manufacturer’s private brand are both located in the line. Consumers’ preferences are uniformly distributed over the sufficiently long line with density one. This kind of assumption is commonly used in operations management literature [3941]. The distance of consumer away from the brand indicates the preference of the brand, such as Nike and Adidas, McDonald’s and KFC, and so on. In this paper, the retailer’s existing brand and the contract manufacturer’s private brand compete for consumers. Each consumer at most buys one unit. The distance of the two brands is , which indicates brand differentiation [39, 40]. A small means that two brands are highly substitutable, and vice versa. Assume that the distance of consumer away from brand is (1 indicates existing brand and 2 indicates contract manufacturer’s private brand).

The utility of consumer from buying brand iswhere indicates the reservation price of consumer and reflects the transportation cost (or disutility), which indicates the intensity of consumer’s preference for a brand. A consumer buys the product only when the consumer can get non-negative utility (). In this paper, the production cost of two brands is the same since they are both produced by the contract manufacturer. Let denote the production cost of two brands. When the retail price is equal to the production cost, the utility of the customer in the middle point must be non-negative, i.e., , or else two brands will not compete. A greater means a higher loyalty.

When two brands compete, the consumer who locates in the non-differentiation point gets the same utility from two brands, that is: . Solving this equation for , we can get . Solving for , we can obtain the demand of the loyal consumers for brand . Following Xu et al. [40] and Xiao et al. [42], when the existing brand and the contract manufacturer’s private brand compete, we can obtain the demand rate for brand during a period.

The market scale is a decreasing function of transportation cost and an increasing function of the reservation price or the brand differentiation .

When the contract manufacturer chooses not to encroach, there is only one brand in the market. If the utility of the consumer is non-negative, consumers will buy the product from the retailer, i.e., , where .

Thus, the demand of the retailer is

3.2. The Optimization Problem of the Retailer and the Contract Manufacturer
3.2.1. Scenario N: When No Member Has Fairness Concern

We use suffix “NN” to indicate the scenario when the retailer has fairness concern under no encroachment. We use suffix “NE” to indicate the scenario when the retailer has fairness concern under encroachment.

When no member has fairness concern, the profit of the contract manufacturer and the retailer is as follows. We use subfix “M” and “R” to indicate the contract manufacturer and the retailer, respectively.

When the contract manufacturer encroaches, the profit functions of the retailer and the contract manufacturer are as follows.where and are shown in equation (2).

By using backward induction, we can get the equilibrium profits of both players as , , , and . The proof can be found in Appendix (Proof of Proposition 1).

3.2.2. Scenario A: When the Retailer Has Fairness Concern

Following Nie and Du [43], Cui et al. [44], and Zhen et al. [9], we adopt utility function as the retailer’s optimization objection. Fehr and Schmidt [8] state that positive benefit and negative benefit of fairness concerns both cause losses to their utility. Thus, in this paper, we both consider disadvantageous inequality and advantageous inequity. We use suffix “AN” to indicate the scenario when the retailer has fairness concern under no encroachment. Suffix “AE” indicates the scenario when the retailer has fairness concern under encroachment.

Under no encroachment, the utility function of the retailer is

The objective function of the contract manufacturer does not change, i.e., .

Under encroachment, the utility function of the retailer is

The objective function of the contract manufacturer does not change, i.e., . and denote the disadvantageous inequity and advantageous inequity concern parameters, respectively, where and [9]. If the retailer’s profit is lower than the equitable payoff, a disadvantageous inequity occurs, resulting in disutility for the retailer. However, if his profit is higher than the equitable payoff, an advantageous inequity also occurs. The greater (or ) is, the more the retailer is concerned about the disadvantageous (or advantageous) inequity. means that the impact of the disadvantageous inequity is higher than that of the advantageous inequity.

Based on the obtained equilibrium profits of the contract manufacturer and the retailer in scenario N (without fairness concerns), when the contract manufacturer does not encroach, the profit of the retailer is higher than that of the contract manufacturer. However, when the contract manufacturer encroaches, the profit of the retailer is lower than that of the contract manufacturer.

Thus, equations (6) and (7) can be rewritten as

3.2.3. Scenario B: When the Contract Manufacturer Has Fairness Concern

Similarly, we use suffix “BN” to denote the scenario when the contract manufacturer has fairness concern under no encroachment. We use suffix “BE” to denote the scenario when the contract manufacturer has fairness concern under encroachment.

Similar to scenario A, under no encroachment, the utility function of the contract manufacturer is

The objective function of the retailer does not change, that is, .

Under encroachment, the utility function of the contract manufacturer is

The objective function of the retailer does not change, that is, .

3.2.4. Scenario C: Both the Retailer and the Contract Manufacturer Have Fairness Concern

In this section, we use suffix “CN” to denote the scenario when the retailer and the contract manufacturer both have fairness concern under no encroachment. We use suffix “CE” to denote the scenario when the retailer and the contract manufacturer both have fairness concern under encroachment.

Similar to scenario A, under no encroachment, the utility function of the retailer and the contract manufacturer is as follows.

Under encroachment, the utility function of the retailer and the contract manufacturer is as follows.

Under each scenario, the time sequence of the game is as follows.(i)At the first stage, the contract manufacturer decides whether to encroach.(ii)At the second stage, the retailer decides profit margin.(iii)At the third stage, the contract manufacturer decides wholesale price. If she decides to encroach, she also needs to decide the retail price of the private brand.

The list of notations is shown in Table 2.

4. Equilibrium

Firstly, the equilibrium in each scenario can be derived by backward induction.

Proposition 1. The equilibriums in scenario N, A, B, and C are summarized in Table 3.

In order to ensure the positivity of the utility, must be satisfied. From Proposition 1, the retail price of the incumbent brand is . Then, we can get because (the reservation price is higher than the production cost). That is to say, the retail price of the new brand is lower than the price of the retailer’s existing brand, which is consistent with practice. Usually, the contract manufacturer’s private brand is more affordable compared with the retailer’s brand. From Proposition 1, we can get Proposition 2.

Proposition 2. The profits of the retailer and the contract manufacturer have following properties.(i); .(ii); , where .(iii); .(iv), where ; , where .

Proposition 2 (i) shows that the retailer’s profit is twice the contract manufacturer’s profit. The retailer who owns a well-known brand shares more profit of the supply chain than the contract manufacturer, which are consistent with practice. The reason is that the retailer leads the supply chain and moves first. There are first-mover advantages [9]. When the contract manufacturer establishes her private brand, she can get more profit than the retailer. The retailer may feel unfair. As a result, the retailer may stop cooperating with the contract manufacturer. Thus, the contract manufacturer may need to consider fairness concern.

Proposition 2 (ii) shows that when increases, the difference between profits of both members will become smaller. That is, when the advantageous inequity concern parameter increases, the share of profit in supply chain is more balanced in Model AN. Because , is a decreasing function of . In scenario A, it is the retailer who has fairness concern. When the disadvantageous inequity concern parameter increases, the share of profit between members will be more imbalanced, which is opposite to the situation when the contract manufacturer does not encroach. That is, the fairness concern of the retailer will decrease his utility. The reason is that it is the contract manufacturer who gains more profit of the supply chain when the contract manufacturer encroaches. If the retailer wants to get more profit, whether the contract manufacturer has fairness concern is more important.

From Proposition 2 (iii), when the disadvantageous inequity increases, the contract manufacturer can get more profits. That is, the fairness concern increases the profit of the contract manufacturer. The share of profit is more balanced.

5. The Encroachment Strategy of the Contract Manufacturer

In this section, we will discuss the contract manufacturer’s encroachment strategy when neither the retailer nor the contract manufacturer has fairness concern. Only when the contract manufacturer can get more profit from encroachment, she will encroach. By comparing the profits of the contract manufacturer under two different encroachment strategies, we can get Proposition 3.

Proposition 3. In different scenarios, the encroachment strategies are different.(i)In scenario N, when no member in the supply chain has fairness concern, the contract manufacturer will always encroach.(ii)In scenario A, only the retailer has fairness concern. When , the contract manufacturer will encroach, or else she will not encroach, where .(iii)In scenario B, only the contract manufacturer has fairness concern. When , the contract manufacturer will encroach, or else she will not encroach.(iv)In scenario C, both the retailer and the contract manufacturer have fairness concern. When , the contract manufacturer will encroach, or else she will not encroach, where and .

Proposition 3 (i) shows that if both retailer and the contract manufacturer do not have fairness concern, the contract manufacturer will always encroach. Selling directly to end-market consumers are more beneficial to the contract manufacturer when no one has fairness in the supply chain. Proposition 3 (ii)–(iv) show the conditions that the contract manufacturer will encroach under different scenarios. When the reservation price is sufficiently high, the contract manufacturer has the motivation to encroach, or else she will not encroach. From Proposition 3, fairness concern has certain strength to stop the contract manufacturer to encroach.

Next, the impact of encroachment on the retailer is analyzed as follows.

In the following, we assume that the equilibrium profit is equal to utility in each scenario to make the expressions simplified. That is, , .

Proposition 4. The impact of contract manufacturer’s encroachment on the retailer is as follows.(i)Under scenario N, when , , or else .(ii)Under scenario A, when , , or else , where .(iii)Under scenario B, , , or else , where .(iv)Under scenario C, when , , or else, , where .

Proposition 4 shows that when the reservation price is sufficiently low, the encroachment of the contract manufacturer benefits the retailer, or else it will harm the benefit of the retailer. That is, the encroachment of the contract manufacturer does not always harm the retailer. The results are similar across four different fairness concern scenarios. Proposition 3 shows the condition that the contract manufacturer will encroach. Thus, the analysis of impact of encroach on the contract manufacturer is omitted.

6. The Impact of Fairness Concern

In this section, we will study the impact of fairness concerns on decisions and profits. Firstly, we will compare the equilibriums in four scenarios (N, A, B, C) under no encroachment. Then, we will compare the equilibriums under encroachment. Finally, we will use numerical examples to illustrate the impact of several key parameters.

Proposition 5. Under no encroachment,(i), , ; when , ; when , ; ; .(ii); ; ; when , . When , ; ; .(iii); ; ; if , when , ; when or , ; ; when , . When , .(iv); ; when , , or else ; when , , or else ; when , , or else ; .

Proposition 5 (i) shows the impact of fairness concerns on the profit margins of the retailer under no encroachment. The profit margin of the retailer in three fairness concern scenarios (A, B, C) are lower than that when there is no fairness concern. That is, when the contract manufacturer does not encroach, the fairness concern decreases the profit margin of the retailer. When the advantageous inequity fairness concern parameter is sufficiently low, the profit margin of the retailer in scenario B is lower than that of scenario A and vice versa when the advantageous inequity fairness concern parameter is sufficiently high. Among four scenarios (N, A, B, C), the profit margin of the retailer under scenario C is the lowest. Proposition 5 (ii) shows the impact of fairness concerns on the wholesale price of the contract manufacturer under no encroachment. The fairness concern increases the wholesale price. When the advantageous inequity fairness concern parameter is sufficiently low, the wholesale price in scenario B is higher than that of scenario A, and vice versa. Among four scenarios (N, A, B, C), the wholesale price under scenario C is the highest. Proposition 5 (iii) shows the impact of fairness concerns on the profit of the retailer under no encroachment. The fairness concern decreases the profit of the retailer. Proposition 5 (iv) shows the impact of fairness concerns on the profit of the contract manufacturer. For the contract manufacturer, the retailer’s fairness concern and her own fairness concern both increase her profit.

Proposition 6. Under encroachment,(i); ; ; when, ; when, ; ; .(ii); ; ; when, ; when, ; ; .(iii); when, , or else , where , ; when , , or else ; ; when , ; when , , where .(iv); , ; when , ; when , ; when , , or else , where ; .

Proposition 6 (i) shows that when the contract manufacturer encroaches, fairness concern will increase the retailer’s profit margin. Among four scenarios (A, B, C, N), the profit margin of the retailer under scenario C is the highest. Proposition 6 (ii) shows that the fairness concern decreases the wholesale price of the contract manufacturer. Among four scenarios (A, B, C, N), the wholesale price of the contract manufacturer under scenario C is the lowest. Proposition 6 (iii) shows that the retailer’s fairness concern decreases his own profit; however, when the contract manufacturer has fairness concern, the profit of the retailer will be increased. Proposition 6 (iv) shows that the fairness concern decreases the contract manufacturer’s profit.

In summary, Table 4 shows the effect of fairness concern on decisions and profits compared with scenario N where there is no fairness concern.

Proposition 7. When the contract manufacturer encroaches, the retail prices of the private brand are the same, i.e., .

Proposition 7 shows that the fairness concern has no impact on the retail price of the contract manufacturer’s private brand.

Then, we investigate the impact of certain key parameters on the profits of both the manufacturer and the retailer. The default parameters are assumed as follows: . All parameters satisfy the conditions ensuring the existence of equilibriums. Several other groups of default parameters are tested as follows: , , and . The results derived from the numerical examples are robust.

Figure 1(a) shows that under no encroachment, when there is no fairness concern of any member, the profit of the retailer is the highest. When the disadvantageous fairness concern parameter is sufficiently low and when both members have fairness concern, the profit of the retailer is the lowest. However, when the disadvantageous fairness concern parameter is sufficiently high and when the contract manufacturer has the fairness concern, the profit of the retailer is the lowest. Figure 1(b) shows that when both members have fairness concern, the profit of the contract manufacturer is the highest. When no one has fairness concern, the profit of the contract manufacturer is the lowest. Figure 1(c) illustrates that when both members have fairness concern, the profit of the whole supply chain is the highest. When disadvantageous fairness concern parameter is sufficiently low and when the contract manufacturer has fairness concern, the profit of the contract manufacturer is the lowest. However, when the disadvantageous fairness concern parameter is sufficiently high, the profit of the contract manufacturer is the lowest when no one has fairness concern. Under scenario C, the profit of the supply chain increases with the disadvantageous inequity parameter. The management insight here is that it is best for the whole supply chain that both members have fairness concern. The profit of the whole supply chain increases when they are more concerned about disadvantageous fairness.

Figure 2 has similar results with Figure 1. Besides, Figure 2 shows that when the advantageous inequity parameter increases, the profit of the retailer under scenario A and scenario C firstly decreases with advantageous inequity parameter and then increases with it. From Figures 1 and 2, it is best for the whole supply chain that both members have fairness concern. The profit of the whole supply chain increases when they are more concerned about fairness.

Figure 3(a) shows that the profit of the retailer is highest when only the contract manufacturer has fairness concern. When only the retailer has fairness concern, the profit of the retailer is the lowest. Under scenarios A and C, the profit of the retailer decreases with the disadvantageous inequity parameter. Figure 3(b) presents that when no one has fairness concern, the contract manufacturer’s profit is the highest and when both members have fairness concern, the profit of the contract manufacturer is the lowest. Figure 3(c) states that it is best for the supply chain that no one has fairness concern. When they are more concerned about disadvantageous inequity, the profit of the whole supply chain will decrease. The management insight here is that when the contract manufacturer has a private brand, it is best for the supply chain that no one has fairness concern.

Figure 4(a) shows that when the advantageous inequity concern parameter is sufficiently high and when both members have fairness concern, the profit of the retailer would be the highest. Figure 4(b) has similar results with Figure 3(b). Figure 4(c) shows that when the advantageous inequity concern parameter is sufficiently low, it is best for the whole supply chain that no one has fairness concern. However, when the advantageous inequity concern parameter is high enough, it is best for the whole supply chain that both members have fairness concern. Under scenarios B and C, the profit of the whole supply chain increases with the advantageous inequity concern parameter when it is sufficiently high. The management insight here is that when the contract manufacturer has a private brand, it is best for the supply chain that no one has fairness concern when the advantageous inequity concern parameter is sufficiently low. However, when the advantageous inequity concern parameter is sufficiently high, it is best for the supply chain that both members have fairness concern.

7. Conclusions

This paper investigates a supply chain consisting of one contract manufacturer and one retailer who owns a well-known brand selling in consumer market. The contract manufacturer provides production service for the retailer. The contract manufacturer’s encroachment strategy and the impact of fairness concern on decisions and profits are investigated. The results show that when no member has fairness concern, the contract manufacturer always has motivation to encroach. However, when the retailer, the contract manufacturer, or both members have fairness concern, only if the reservation price is sufficiently high, the contract manufacturer will encroach. That is, the fairness concern has certain strength to stop the contract manufacturer to establish a private brand. When the reservation price is sufficiently low, the encroachment of the contract manufacturer benefits the retailer, or else it will harm the benefit of the retailer. Under encroachment strategy, the fairness concern decreases the profit margin of the retailer and increases wholesale price. However, under no encroachment strategy, the impact of fairness concern on pricing decisions is opposite except that the fairness concern has no impact on the retail price of the private brand. Under no encroachment strategy, the fairness concern has negative impact on the retailer’s profit. However, under encroachment, the manufacturer’s fairness concern can increase the retailer’s profit. The fairness concern decreases the contract manufacturer’s profit no matter what the form it is. Numerical examples show that under no encroachment, it is best for the whole supply chain that both members have fairness concern. The profit of the whole supply chain increases when they are more concerned about fairness. However, under encroachment, it is best for the supply chain that no one has fairness concern when the advantageous inequity concern parameter is sufficiently low. When the advantageous inequity concern parameter is sufficiently high, it is best for the supply chain that both members have fairness concern.

This study can be extended in the following aspects in the future research. Firstly, this paper derives demand function from the Hotelling model which indicates that the contract manufacturer’s private brand has symmetric position with retailer’s existing brand. However, consumers may have different perception for different brands in reality, especially for new brands. Thus, the demand function can be modelled in a different way. Secondly, this research assumes that supply chain members are completely information symmetric. It would be interesting to investigate how the information asymmetry affects the results. Thirdly, in big data era, real data can be used to make the model closer to the reality.

Appendix

A. Proof of Proposition 1

A.1. Equilibrium under Scenario NN

Because , is a concave function of . By solving the first-order condition , we can get the reaction function of the contract manufacturer . By Inserting into retailer’s profit function, we can get . Because , is a concave function of . By solving the first-order condition , we can get the optimal profit function of the retailer as . Then, we can get the contract manufacturer’s optimal wholesale price as . Finally, we can get the profit of the retailer and the contract manufacturer as and , respectively.

A.2. Equilibrium under Scenario NE

Because and , is a concave function of . By solving the first-order conditions , we can get the reaction function of the contract manufacturer and . By inserting and into the retailer’s profit function, we can get . Because , is a concave function of . By solving the first-order condition , we can get the optimal profit function of the existing brand as . By inserting into and , we can get the contract manufacturer’s optimal decisions and . The retailer’s profit is . The contract manufacturer’s profit is .

A.3. Equilibrium under Scenario AN

Because , is a concave function of . By solving the first-order condition , we can get the reaction function of the contract manufacturer . By inserting into retailer’s utility function, we can get . . Only if , is a concave function of . By solving the first-order condition , we can get the optimal profit function of the retailer as . Then, we can get the contract manufacturer’s optimal wholesale price as . Finally, we can get the utility of the retailer as . The profit of the contract manufacturer is . In order to ensure the positivity of the profit margin, must be satisfied. Thus, can ensure both concavity and positivity of the equilibrium.

A.4. Equilibrium under Scenario AE

Because and , is a concave function of . By solving the first-order conditions , we can get the reaction function of the contract manufacturer and . By inserting and into the retailer’s utility function, we can get . Because , is a concave function of . By solving the first-order condition , we can get the optimal profit function of the existing brand as . By inserting into and , we can get the contract manufacturer’s optimal decisions and . The retailer’s utility is . The contract manufacturer’s profit is . Note that must be non-negative, or else the retailer will abandon the supply chain. That is, .

A.5. Equilibrium under Scenario BN

Because , is a concave function of . By solving the first-order condition , we can get the reaction function of the contract manufacturer . By inserting into retailer’s profit function, we can get . Because , is a concave function of . By solving the first-order condition , we can get the optimal profit function of the retailer as . Then, we can get the contract manufacturer’s optimal wholesale price as . Also, we can get the utility of the contract manufacturer as . The profit of the retailer is .

A.6. Equilibrium under Scenario BE

Because and, is a concave function of . By solving the first-order conditions , we can get the reaction function of the contract manufacturer and . By inserting and into the retailer’s utility function, we can get . . Only if , is a concave function of . By solving the first-order condition , we can get the optimal profit function of the existing brand as . By inserting into and , we can get the contract manufacturer’s optimal decisions and . The retailer’s profit is . The contract manufacturer’s utility is .

A.7. Equilibrium under Scenario CN

Because , is a concave function of . By solving the first-order condition , we can get the reaction function of the contract manufacturer as . By inserting into retailer’s profit function, we can get . Because , when , i.e., , is a concave function of . By solving the first-order condition , we can get the optimal profit function of the retailer as . Then, we can get the contract manufacturer’s optimal wholesale price as . Also, we can get the utility of the contract manufacturer as . The profit of the retailer is . In order to ensure the positivity of the profit margin, must be satisfied. Because , can ensure both concavity and positivity of the equilibrium.

A.8. Equilibrium under Scenario CE

Because and, is a concave function of . By solving the first-order conditions , we can get the reaction function of the contract manufacturer as and . By inserting and into the retailer’s utility function, we can get . . Let . Because , is a convex function of . Let , and we can get two roots and . Since , we can omit this root. Thus, when , . Then, is a concave function of . By solving the first-order condition , we can get the optimal profit function of the existing brand as . By inserting into and , we can get the contract manufacturer’s optimal decisions as and . Then, we can get the retailer and the contract manufacturer’s utility.

B. Proof of Proposition 3

B.1. The Encroachment Strategy of Scenario N

From Propositions 1, the profit of the contract manufacturer under two different encroachment strategies is and , respectively. . Only when , the contract manufacturer will establish her private brand. That is, . Because we assume that the reservation price is always higher than the cost (), is always satisfied.

B.2. The Encroachment Strategy of Scenario A

From Propositions 1, the profit of the contract manufacturer under two different encroachment strategies is and , respectively. . Only when , the contract manufacturer will establish her private brand. That is, , where .

B.3. The Encroachment Strategy of Scenario B

From Propositions 1, the utility of the contract manufacturer under two different encroachment strategies is and , respectively. . Only when , the contract manufacturer will establish her private brand. That is, .

B.4. The Encroachment Strategy of Scenario C

From Propositions 1, the utility of the contract manufacturer under two different encroachment strategies is and , respectively, where .. Only when , the contract manufacturer will establish her private brand. That is, , where , .

That is, , where and .

C. Proof of Proposition 4

(i); when , , or else .(ii); when , , or else , where .(iii), , , or else , where .(iv); when , , or else, , where .

D. Proof of Proposition 5

that is, .that is, .

Since , . Let. . That is, is a decreasing function of . Let , and we can get a root as . When , . We know that ; thus, . Then, we can get . That is, .

Because, . Let. is a linear function of . . That is, is an increasing function of . Let , and we can get a root as . ; thus, . When , , . When , , .

From and , we know that . Let. Because , is a concave function of . By solving , we can get two roots , where . When , and .

Let . We can get the unique root as . Because , is a decreasing function of . Thus, when , , that is, .

Since , , and the reservation price of the consumer is higher than the cost, i.e., . As a result, . . As a result, . , .

Solving , we can get a unique root as . , is a decreasing function of . Because , . When , . When , .

Because , , and , when , , and when , . Because and , is always satisfied.

Solving , we can get a unique root . . is an increasing function of . Because , .because , , and , .that is, .because , . Because , .

Let . . is a concave function of . Let , and we can get two roots:

Thus, when and , , then . When or , , then.

Let , which is a linear function of . Let , and we can get a unique root . Because , is an increasing function of . When , , then . When , . Because and must be satisfied, .

Let , which is a linear function of . Let , and we can get a unique root . Because , is an increasing function of . When , , then . When , .

Because , , . . Because , .where . Because , is a concave function of . By solving , we can get two roots:

Thus, when, or else .where . . is a convex function of . Let , and we can get two roots:

Thus, when , , then , or else.where

Because , and , and . When , , then , or else .where . Because , is a concave function of . By solving , we can get too roots , where . , and. Thus, when , .

E. Proof of Proposition 6

Thus, .

Thus, .

Because , , and . Thus, ; then, .

When , , i.e., . When , . Note that . Thus, when , . When , .

Because , , and . Thus, .

Because , , and , , i.e., .

Thus, .

Thus, .and thus .

Because , , and when , , , or else . Note that .

Thus, .

Thus, .

Thus, .

Thus, .where . Because , is a concave function of . By solving for , we can get two roots {}, where

Thus, when , , or else .

When , , or else .

When , , or else . Note that and ; thus, .

Let . . is a concave function of . By solving , we can get two roots {}, where

Because and , there is a unique root between the interval . Thus, when , . When , .

Thus, .

Thus, .where . Because , is a convex function of . By solving , we can get two roots , where both roots are greater than . Thus, in the interval , . As a result, .where . is a linear function of . Because , is a decreasing function of . Solving for , we can get a unique root . Thus, when , ; when , .

When , , or else .where . Because , is an increasing function of . By solving , we can get a unique root . Thus, when , . When , . Note that and , and thus are always satisfied.

Data Availability

All data generated or analyzed during this study are included within this article. The author is willing to share the implementation scripts in the form of some MATHEMATICA nb-files with the interested reader.

Conflicts of Interest

The author declares that there are no conflicts of interest regarding the publication of this paper.

Acknowledgments

This study was supported by the National Natural Science Foundation of China (71601111, 71774109, and 71702101) and Natural Science Foundation of Shanghai (18ZR1416900).