Abstract

This paper investigates the reward-penalty mechanism (RPM) implemented by the government in a closed-loop supply chain (CLSC) with asymmetric information. The manufacturer produces and sells products to consumers, while the collection of waste electrical and electronic equipment (WEEE) is delegated to the third-party collector, the one who has private information about the collection effort level. An information screening contract for the manufacturer is put forward to obtain the private information from the third-party collector, which is composed of buy-back price and franchise fee. By utilizing principal-agent theory, two cases are mainly examined including the CLSC without the RPM and the CLSC with the RPM. The results demonstrate that (i) the information screening contract is effective in capturing the collector’s collection effort level, (ii) raising the buy-back price to motivate the third-party collector is confirmed to perform well on enhancing the collection quantity from consumers, (iii) H-type collector collects more WEEEs and earns more profits than L-type collector, and (iv) the RPM improves the collection quantity of the enterprise and reaps more environmental benefits. The numerical results verify the validity of the contract and the feasibility of the RPM.

1. Introduction

The problem of waste electrical and electronic equipment (WEEE) is becoming increasingly difficult for the government to manage [1, 2]. As the gigantic benefits of remanufacturing in the field of environment and economy, the concept of the closed-loop supply chain (CLSC) has been extensively developed in recent years [36]. In addition, there exist growing enterprises to regulate strategies moderately in response to CLSC management. For example, Dell saves more costs than ever before in manufacturing and remanufacturing processes.

Additionally, many manufacturers have taken the initiative to undertake the responsibility for remanufacturing WEEE in the CLSC, while the collection of WEEE is delegated to third-party collectors who possess expertise and efficiency in the collection. Therefore, the third-party collector plays an important role in the collection process [710]. For instance, ReCellular Inc., the largest cellular telephone remanufacturer in the United States, outsources the collection operation to third-party collectors and provides applicable incentives to stimulate collecting used phones [11]. The third-party collector gathers WEEE from consumers and then sells reusable materials to the manufacturer, which prevents the environment from damaging by WEEE and reduces the cost of manufacturing products.

The enterprise makes appropriate decisions based on a large amount of information, such as historical information, online information, and forecast information [12, 13]. However, few enterprises are willing to share private information with others [14]. In particular, the company positioned at an unfair disadvantage in capturing information will spend more time and energy to obtain and examine the authenticity of the information. For instance, some delegated collectors may have more accurate information about the collection than manufacturers [15], as the collection effort level remains the private information of collectors and is rarely known by manufacturers. Under such circumstances, manufacturers hardly determine the buy-back price for collectors who are accustomed to cheating manufacturers to earn more profits. Therefore, the information-poor company chooses to cooperate with other members in the supply chain and designs effective contracts to obtain the real asymmetric information.

Furthermore, the supervision of the government plays an essential role in the CLSC. In recent years, a number of environmental legislations have been implemented in many countries. In respect of collection and disposal of WEEE, China has promulgated the Circular Economy Promotion Law of the People’s Republic of China, Administrative Measures for the Prevention and Control of Environmental Pollution by Electronic Waste, and Regulation on the Administration of the Recovery and Disposal of Waste Electrical and Electronic Products. On September 21, 2021, at the general debate of the 76th Session of the United Nations General Assembly, President Xi Jinping proposed a global development initiative of “Accelerating green and low-carbon Transformation for Green Recovery and development” and reiterated that “China will strive to achieve carbon peak by 2030 and carbon neutral by 2060.” In European Union, legislation such as the End-of-Life Vehicle Directive and the Waste Electrical and Electronic Equipment Directive is of course familiar [16]. Japan, Germany, and other countries have also formulated preferential tax policies, preferential price policies, garbage collection policies, and so on to improve the enthusiasm of enterprises and citizens to participate in recycling. By the end of 2005, more than 50 governments had implemented green procurement to guide market demand. The government’s intervention guarantees the effective operation of CLSC. Besides, a series of environmental protection mechanisms have been offered, such as subsidies and tax exemption. Reward-penalty mechanism (RPM) is intended as the policy to encourage CLSC members to perform collection efficiently, which operates with the targeted collection quantity and the reward-penalty intensity. Particularly, in a two-stage CLSC, the manufacturer produces and sells products to consumers, and the collection of WEEE is deputed to the third-party collector. The third-party collector is assumed to choose different collection effort levels including high level and low level, all of which are the third-party collector’s private information. Therefore, the third-party collector is divided into an H-type collector and an L-type collector. The manufacturer masters the probability of the third-party collector who adopts a high collection effort level. An information screening contract is designed to filter the collection effort information of the third-party collector. In addition, RPM is considered for the government to force the manufacturer to use collected materials as soon as possible. Under such circumstances, the manufacturer will receive rewards (penalties) if the collection quantity is more (less) than the targeted one. Specifically, we address the following research questions:(i)Can the information screening contract help the manufacturer identify private information from the third-party collector?(ii)How does the RPM impact the members of the CLSC with asymmetric information?(iii)How does the manufacturer increase the collection quantity collected by a third-party collector to avoid being punished by the government?

The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. Section 2 is an overview of the relevant literature. Section 3 gives the model descriptions, notations, and assumptions. In Section 4, Case 1 investigates the decision-making of the CLSC without RPM and Case 2 investigates the CLSC with RPM. We compare two cases to explore the impacts of RPM. Numerical studies are given to validate models in Section 5. Finally, Section 6 gives the conclusions, discusses managerial implications, and then presents future research directions.

2. Literature Review

Our paper mainly involves three aspects of literature: the third-party collection channel, the asymmetric information, and the government’s intervention in the CLSC. We review the relevant literature in the following order. In Section 2.1, we address the literature on the third-party collection channel in the CLSC. Section 2.2 discusses the literature on asymmetric information in the supply chain. Literature concentrated on the government’s intervention in the CLSC is displayed in Section 2.3.

2.1. The Third-Party Collection Channel in the CLSC

To enhance the efficiency of collection, a little literature focuses on the third-party collection channel in the CLSC. Savaskan et al. [7] solve the problem of reverse channel structure selection for recycling products. Huang et al. [8] conduct the optimal strategies of the CLSC by examining the competition between the retailer and the third-party collector. Centralized decisions and decentralized decisions are analyzed, respectively, to obtain managerial insights. The result demonstrates that dual-channel recovery is better than that in a single channel. Giovanni and Zaccour [17] verify whether a remanufacturer should manage the own waste collection or outsource collection to a collector. The result illustrates that the manufacturer outsources the product collection only when an outsourcer performs environmentally and operationally better. When outsourcing is convenient, the manufacturer gives priority to the retailer in the same conditions. Chu et al. [9] investigate that the third-party collector mode serving multiple manufacturers is better than the individual retailer-managed mode and the manufacturer-managed mode. With the concentrating operation in companies, like third-party logistics, most manufacturers outsource the collection operation to third-party collectors. Wan and Hong [18] analyze the optimal pricing and recycling decisions in CLSC including a manufacturer, a retailer, and two collectors. The transfer prices to two collectors are either uniform or different. The result reveals that the supply chain is more inclined to afford two collectors with different transfer prices. Wang et al. [19] establish two closed-loop supply chain models that have dual collection channels. The result draws that in any model, as consumers’ preference for third-party collection channels increases, the third-party’s optimal collection price always decreases. Zheng et al. [20] explore the reverse channel choice for the manufacturer and the design of coordination mechanisms in CLSCs in the midst of dual competitive sale channels. They consider three recycling channel structures: manufacturer collecting, retailer collecting, and third-party collecting structures. It can be seen that third-party collection has become one of the recycling channels widely studied by many scholars. Therefore, in this study, we consider that the manufacturer delegates the collection operation to a third-party collector and then buys collected materials that can be reused from this collector.

2.2. The Asymmetric Information in the Supply Chain

To obtain full information about the collection effort level and collection, cost remains extremely difficult for the manufacturer. Therefore, designing an appropriate contract is crucial for the manufacturer to obtain more private information and maximize profit. Corbett and Tang [21] present six scenarios where the consumers’ cost structure is full and incomplete information in wholesale-pricing schemes, two-part linear schemes, and two-part nonlinear schemes, respectively. Zhang et al. [22] utilize a contract to coordinate a dual-channel supply chain under demand uncertainty and production cost uncertainty, respectively. They find that both the manufacturer and the retailer benefit from coordinating contracts when demand increases or production costs decrease. Wang et al. [15] consider the role of an information screening contract when the retailer shares the collection effort level information with the manufacturer in CLSC. Ma et al. [23] design the optimal contract for a supply chain where the manufacturer’s social responsibility is asymmetric information. Zhang and Zhang [24] research a two-period supply chain where the supplier sells products through a retailer who has private market potential information. Wang et al. [25] design the contract mechanism for a supply chain consisting of one risk-neutral retailer and one risk-neutral supplier who has private production costs. In this study, we investigate asymmetric information of the third-party collector and design information screening contracts for the manufacturer to obtain that asymmetric information. Sun et al. [26] examine manufacturer encroachment with the cost reduction decision under asymmetric information and obtain some insights related to information management. Wang et al. [27] study how to achieve VMI supply chain coordination in an asymmetric information environment. The results indicate that the private information of the manufacturer and the retailer can coordinate the supply chain under the asymmetric information of bilateral information.

2.3. The Government’s Intervention in the CLSC

The key purpose of our study is to investigate the impact of the government on the CLSC. Xie and Ma [28] claim that government as a supervisor plays a significant role to encourage collection operations in CLSC. Rahman and Subramanian [29] suggest that the government’s legislation motivates the recycling operation in the computer industry. Wang et al. [30] take RPM into account to CLSC with a competitive dual collection channel and find that RPM improves the collection of waste products. Zand et al. [31] explore the optimal pricing and recycling in a two-stage closed-loop supply chain under the government limitation. The study demonstrates that the limitation benefits the recycling activities and the profit of the retailer at the expense of the manufacturer’s profit. Chen and Akmalul ’Ulya [32] explore the green efforts of the manufacturer and the retailer in remanufacturing under the RPM. They find that the mechanism improves the green effort level and profits of both alike. Wang et al. [33] study the RPM for collection responsibility sharing in CLSC. The study reveals that it is optimal to impose the collection responsibility on the manufacturer, which is most beneficial to social welfare and collection rate. The government should impose higher reward-penalty intensity on the manufacturer. Besides, high reward-penalty intensity improves the social welfare level. Zhang et al. [34] study optimal pricing and remanufacturing mode in a closed-loop supply chain of WEEE under government fund policy. The results show that it can increase supply chain members’ profits and promote the recycling and remanufacturing of used WEEE products when government fund policy parameters meet a certain range.

Previous literature contributes to the theory of CLSC. Table 1 reveals the main differences between our study and the existing literature, which concentrate on three aspects. First, literature has investigated the asymmetric information of the manufacturer, retailer, and consumer. For example, Wang et al. [15] study the asymmetric information of the retailer. However, the collector plays an increasingly significant role in the CLSC by virtue of professional collection ability. Therefore, we consider the asymmetric information about the collection effort level of the collector who is responsible for the collection operation and then analyze how to design an information screening contract for the manufacturer to capture the private information of the collector. Second, we further consider RPM to examine the influence of RPM implemented by the government on the manufacturer’s decisions, which is mentioned in Wang et al. [15]. Finally, we develop the direct channel and assume that the manufacturer sells products to consumers directly, which is different from Wang et al. [30].

3. Problem Formulation

3.1. Model Description

The structure of CLSC is displayed in Figure 1. The solid line represents the direction of forwarding logistics and the dotted line indicates the direction of reverse logistics. Besides, some specific parameters are shown in Table 2.

In forward logistics, the manufacturer sells products at a retail price to customers directly. In reverse logistics, the third-party collector recycles WEEE from consumers with collection price . The manufacturer buys the collected components from a third-party collector with a buy-back price and charges the collector a franchise fee. Franchise fee here refers to a fee paid by the third-party collector to the manufacturer, so as to use the brand influence of manufacturing to improve their profits. In practice, the franchise fee is a common phenomenon, such as franchise stores [17]. Besides, the collection effort level of the third-party collector is segmented into H-type and L-type, which is asymmetric private information for the manufacturer. We design an information screening contract for the manufacturer to obtain private information. The information screening contract is expressed as , which is composed of buy-back price and franchise fee.

3.2. Model Assumptions

The following assumptions are made for developing the model of CLSC.(i)We consider the optimization problem in single-cycle CLSC where the third-party collector has private information and the information of other members is symmetrical.(ii)The products have the same quality and retail price whether using new materials or recycled components. These products correspond with the leasing office’s equipment, such as photocopiers and printers [33, 35, 36].(iii)We have the priority of using recycled components in the production, while new materials are used only when recycled components are exhausted because of the lower cost of recycled components [1, 37].(iv)The unit cost of using new materials is larger than the unit cost of using recycled components; i.e., [9, 38].(v)The manufacturer and third-party collector are risk neutral; they all devote themselves to achieving the optimal profits [2, 7, 38].(vi)The cost of collection effort level is a quadratic function. The function is given by , and . Besides, we have and [1, 7, 39].(vii)The market demand is , where indicates the market size. In addition, is the impact of random factors in the market and its distribution function is (). Besides, the probability density function is and the probability distribution function is . Further, the probability density function can be expressed as , where “x” represents the range of values of [40].(viii)The quantity of the collected WEEE is a linear function of both the collection effort level and the collection price, i.e., [15], .

4. The Model

4.1. The CLSC without RPM (Case 1)

In this section, we consider a benchmark model where the manufacturer is responsible for producing and selling products. The third-party collector, who has private information of collection effort level, is in charge of collecting used products from consumers. An information screening contract is designed for the manufacturer to obtain the private information of the third-party collector. Based on assumptions in Section 3.2, we develop the model as follows.

When the collector adopts an information screening contract , the expected profit of the manufacturer can be written as follows:

In equation (1), . When , the recycled components satisfy the needs of production. When , both the recycled materials and new materials satisfy the needs of production.

When the collector selects contract , the expected profit of the manufacturer is represented by

In equation (2), when , the production is fulfilled by utilizing the recycled materials. Otherwise, when , the production is satisfied by using recycled components and new materials jointly.

If the collector exerts collection effort and chooses contract , the expected profit of the collector is

If the collector adopts collection effort and chooses contract , the expected profit of the collector is denoted by

When the collector selects collection effort and adopts contract , the profit of the collector is given as

As the collector is collection effort but chooses contract , then collector’s expected profit is

In this case, the objective function and constraints are expressed ass.t.

Equations (10) and (11) are participation constraints that guarantee that the expected profit of the collector is higher than the case without constraints. Equations (12) and (13) are incentive compatibility constraints to avoid the false information provided by the collector.

With the Lagrange multiplier method, the optimization problem and the optimal results can be derived as follows:

The solving process is shown in the Appendix.

With the optimal outcomes, we have Proposition 1.

Proposition 1. (i)In the information screening contract , the optimal decisions are and (ii)In the information screening contract , the optimal decisions are , (iii)The optimal collection prices are and Proposition 1 gives the optimal information screening contract which includes the optimal buy-back price and the franchise fee. Such a contract can ensure the manufacturer obtains the collector’s collection effort level effectively in CLSC.

Substituting the optimal collection prices into , we have the optimal collection quantities. By comparing the collection quantities of different types, we can obtain Proposition 2.

Proposition 2. The H-type collector collects higher quantities than the L-type collector; i.e., .

Proof. By calculation, we have . With and , we can easily obtain .
Proposition 2 implies that the H-type collector makes more effort to collect WEEE and then she can reap more WEEE than the L-type collector. We can further obtain that the collection quantity increases in the probability of the third-party collector being an H-type, which also indicates that an H-type collector will pay more attention to the collection.
Consider that many governments are endeavoring to regulate WEEE and prevent pollution. We next take a government’s management into account in the CLSC with asymmetric information.

4.2. The CLSC with RPM (Case2)

In this section, the government implements RPM on the manufacturer in CLSC. The government rewards the manufacturer when the collection target is overfulfilled otherwise, the manufacturer will be penalized.

When the collector adopts contract , the expected profit of the manufacturer is

In equation (20), . Enough WEEE materials satisfy the needs of production when . When , manufacturer utilizes recycled components and new materials for meeting production.

Similarly, if the collector chooses contract , the expected profit of the manufacturer is expressed as

In equation (21), . When , the needs of production are satisfied with recycled components. When , the needs of production are met by using recycled components and new materials jointly.

If the collection effort of collector is and the collector chooses contract , the expected profit of collector is

When the collector adopts collection effort but chooses contract , the expected profit of collector is denoted as

If the collector’s collection effort is and the collector selects contract , the expected profit of the collector is expressed as

If the collector’s collection effort is but the collector chooses contract , the expected profit of collector is

In the CLSC under RPM, the objective function and constraints are expressed ass.t.

Equations (29) and (30) are participation constraints to ensure that the collector accepts the contract. Equations (31) and (32) are incentive compatibility constraints. The incentive compatibility constraints enable the collector to share the right collection effort level information.

Solving this model with the Lagrange multiplier method, we obtain

The solving process is shown in the Appendix.

With the optimal results above, we give Proposition 3.

Proposition 3. (a)Under the RPM, the optimal information screening contract is given by , (b)Under the RPM, the optimal information screening contract is given by Proposition 3 gives the optimal information screening contract which includes the optimal buy-back price and the franchise fee in CLSC with RPM. In this case, the information screening contract also ensures that the manufacturer obtains the collector’s private information effectively.

4.3. Comparison of the Equilibrium Solutions

In this section, we compare the optimal results with and without RPM to find managerial insights. The conclusions are shown in the following propositions.

Proposition 4. Under the RPM, the manufacturer increases the buy-back price, and the collector raises the collection price and gets a higher collection quantity.

Proof. Comparing equation (33) with equation (14), we have . Similarly, we get by comparing equation (34) with equation (15). Based on the results of comparisons, the buy-back price is enhanced when the government implements RPM. Comparing equation (37) with equation (18), we obtain . Similarly, we have . Besides, comparing the collection quantity of different cases, we obtain and .
Proposition 4 indicates that the RPM induces the collector to obtain a higher collection quantity efficaciously. To reach the target collection quantity and avoid getting a penalty from the government, the manufacturer will increase the buy-back price to stimulate the collector under RPM, and then the collector increases the collection price to raise the collection quantity. From these comparisons, we obtain that the RPM is efficient in enhancing the collection of WEEE’s quantity.

Proposition 5. Under the RPM, the manufacturer charges more franchise fees to ensure profit.

Proof. Combining equations (35) with equation (16), we have . Besides, by contrasting equation (36) with equation (17), we get .
From Propositions 4 and 5, we obtain that the manufacturer increases the buy-back price to stimulate the third-party collector to collect more WEEEs under the RPM. However, to obtain more profits, the manufacturer charges the collector more franchise fees.

5. Numerical Examples

5.1. Analysis of the CLSC without RPM

A numerical analysis is provided to illustrate the optimal decisions under Case 1. Based on data by examining several companies and combining with actual situations [13, 22], we let , , , , , , , . And Table 3 gives the optimal decisions of Case 1 with different . By analyzing Table 3, we find the following.

As increases, the buy-back price , collection price , and collection quantity are unchanged, while the buy-back price , collection price , and collection quantity decrease. In equation (14), differentiating with respect to , we obtain . That illustrates the manufacturer offers H-type collectors a fixed buy-back price whatever changes. Similarly, we have . From equations (18) and (19), we obtain collection price and buy-back price having the same trend. Similarly, the collection quantity and the collection price have the same trend. Those trends are consistent with Table 3.

With increasing, the franchise fee increases, while decreases. In equation (16), we can get , which implies that the manufacturer charges L-type collector lower franchise fee with a larger . In equation (17), we get . Besides, we have , , and , and hence, we obtain . That proves the manufacturer charges H-type collector more franchise fee with becoming larger. Therefore, the manufacturer ensures his profit by charging more franchise fees.

With increasing, the expected profit of manufacturer increases, whereas the expected profit of collector decreases when H-type collector opts the . When the L-type collector adopts , the manufacturer’s profit decreases with increasing, and the third-party collector gets the conserved profit. When the H-type collector chooses , the manufacturer increases the franchise fee with increasing. That reduces the collector’s profit but the H-type collector’s profit is still larger than the conserved profit. Therefore, the H-type collector accepts the screening contract for more profits. When the L-type collector opts , the franchise fee decreases with increasing. The L-type collector gets only the conserved profit. Therefore, the L-type collector also accepts the screening contract.

5.2. Analysis of the CLSC with RPM

To investigate the impact of the RPM, we adopt the same parameters as these in Section 5.1. Besides, we have , . The numerical results of CLSC with RPM are shown in Figures 27.

As shown in Figures 24, the buy-back price, collection price, and collection quantity are increasing with the reward-penalty intensity getting larger. In equation (33), we obtain . And in equation (34), we have . Besides, differentiating on , we obtain . And taking derivative of about , we have . Besides, we have and , respectively. Besides, from Proposition 4, we get , , and . The results show that the buy-back price, collection price, and collection quantity are enhanced under the RPM. The government guides the process of collection effectively in CLSC.

As shown in Figure 5, the franchise fee and is enhanced with the increasing reward-penalty intensity. In equations (35) and (36), we have and . Besides, from Proposition 5, and can be clearly obtained. Therefore, the manufacturer enhances franchise fees to achieve more profits when increasing reward-penalty intensity.

In Figure 6, the expected profits of the manufacturer and are increasing initially and then are decreasing with increasing reward-penalty intensity. Figure 7 shows that the expected profit of the collector increases with increasing reward-penalty intensity, while the expected profit is the conserved profit. Furthermore, we find that the expected profits of the manufacturer are decreasing when the reward-penalty intensity increases from 10 to 20. The collection quantity exceeds the targeted collection quantity at the beginning, and then, it gradually rises when the reward-penalty intensity increases from 20 to 40. Under RPM, the H-type collector enhances the buy-back price and his expected profit grows with the increase of reward-penalty intensity. The L-type collector obtains only the conserved profits. Besides, we find and , which indicate that the expected profit of manufacturer under RPM is lower than the case without RPM. When , the expected profit of the manufacturer under RPM is extremely close to that without RPM. But the profit of the collector under RPM is larger than the case without RPM, which means the collector is stimulated by RPM and has a positive attitude for collecting WEEEs. If the reward-penalty intensity keeps increasing, the expected profit of the manufacturer will outstrip his expected profit under the case without RPM. It explains that the manufacturer gets more expected profit with the increase of reward-penalty intensity.

6. Conclusions, Managerial Implications, and Future Research

This paper explores the reward-penalty mechanism (RPM) in a closed-loop supply chain (CLSC), where the manufacturer delegates the WEEE collection to a third-party collector, who has the private information of the collection effort level. We provide an information screening contract for the manufacturer to capture the private information of the collector. The optimal decision-making results, with principal-agent theory, are obtained by solving the models. The conclusions and managerial implications are as follows:(i)The information screening contract makes it feasible that the manufacturer obtains third-party collector’s collection effort level with and without RPM. Therefore, for manufacturers, we recommend that they should adopt an information screening contract to obtain other corporations’ private information. In addition, they increase the buy-back price to stimulate the third-party collector to collect waste products under RPM and to avoid punishment by the government.(ii)The RPM has a significant impact on the performance of CLSC with asymmetric information. The profits of the collector with RPM are larger than those without RPM. And the collection quantity is enhanced by implementing RPM. For government managers, we suggest that they provide RPM to improve the efficiency of enterprises for raising the collection quantity and bringing more environmental benefits.(iii)H-type collector collects more WEEEs and earns more profits than L-type collector. With the information screening contract, the H-type collector chooses the contract and the L-type collector chooses the contract . Therefore, for third-party collectors, we propose that they cooperate with the manufacturer actively. Although the manufacturer charges more franchise fees, they also increase the buy-back price, and the profits of collectors become larger than the case without RPM. Furthermore, regardless of RPM, collectors should ensure that the collection effort level is H-type for obtaining more profits. Simultaneously, when cooperating with the manufacturer, collectors should truthfully deliver the right private information for obtaining more profits. This conclusion complements the research on asymmetric information of third-party collectors in Wang et al. [15].

6.1. Future Research

In this paper, we assume that enterprises are risk neutral, but in practice, enterprises have risk preference or risk averse. Therefore, the one of research directions is that the impact of the government’s RPM on CLSC with asymmetric information when enterprises have different risk preferences, such as risk averse and risk loving. Moreover, we only suppose that the third-party collector has private information. In most cases, every enterprise in a supply chain has private information. Therefore, another research direction is that the other CLSC members also have private information besides third-party collectors.

Appendix

A. The process of solving Case 1

Assume ; we then have

According to equations (A.8) and (A.9), and are solved out. Then, taking derivative of and in the light of limit derivation rule, the following two formulas are obtained by and :

Because and , equations (A.3) and (A.5) have the maximum values, respectively. By solving equations (A.14) and (A.15), we obtain the optimal values of and.

To obtain the optimal results of the model, we need to solve out and . In terms of the limit derivation rule, we get the partial derivative and make it equal 0. The formulas are as follows:

Because and , equations (A.3) and (A.5) are convex, respectively. By solving equations (A.18) and (A.19), we get

To obtain the optimal solutions of this model, we take , , and into equations (A.1)–(A.6), and the following formulas are obtained:

Considering and , we get . The constraint can be ignored.

The relative Lagrange multiplier of equations (A.10), (A.12), and (A.13) are denoted by , , and , respectively. So we get

Taking partial derivative of equation (A.28), we obtain the optimal condition:

Solving the optimal conditions of , we get and . We get and . Further, we acquire .

(Disproof: Assume , according to conditions; the correspondent inequality equation (A.13) must be equality. Similarly, means constraint equation (A.12) is equality. So, we have and from the two constraints equations (A.12) and (A.13). In such setting, the third-party collector faces the same contracts when he chooses contract or contract; thus, the contracts are mixed up. However, the collectors who choose different contracts are intermingled and harm the interests of enterprises under the mixed-up contracts. So, the assumption is not supported and then we obtain .)

Taking , , and into the optimal conditions of , we obtain

Taking function , , and into equations (A.33) and (A.34), and solving out equations (A.35) and (A.36), we can derive the optimal buy-back price of different types, respectively.

, we let , and then we get

Similarly, we let , and then we get

The process of solving Case 2.

Proof. where and .
According to (A.46) and (A.47), we obtain and . Then, taking derivative of and in the light of limit derivation rule, the following two formulas can be obtained by and .
Because and , then from above equations, we obtain equations (A.52) and (A.53):To obtain the optimal results of the model, we need to solve out and . In terms of the limit derivation rule, we get the partial derivative and make it equal 0. and .
Because and , then by solving equations (A.14) and (A.15), from above equations, we solve out (A.54) and (A.55):To obtain the optimal results of the model, we take , , , and into equations (A.39)–(A.44) and acquire the following:In the original model, equation (A.49) can be ignored because .
The relative Lagrange multiplier of equations (A.48), (A.50), and (A.51) are denoted by , , and . So we obtainTaking partial derivative of equation (A.62) obtains the following optimal conditions of :After solving the optimal conditions of we get and which shows and . Further, we acquire .
(Disproof: Assume . According to conditions, the correspondent inequality equation (A.51) must be equality. Similarly, means constraint equation (A.50) is equality. So, we have and from the two constraints equations (A.50) and (A.51). At this time, the third-party collector faces the same contracts when he chooses contract or contract; thus, the contracts are mixed up. However, the collector who chooses different contracts is intermingled and harms the interests of enterprises under the mixed-up contracts. So, the assumption is not provided and we obtain .)
Taking , , and into the optimal conditions of , we can acquireTaking function as well as formulas and into the above two formulas, we solve out equations (A.65) and (A.66):Solving , we obtainSimilarly, because , equation (A.50) is equality.Thus, ; we find

Data Availability

No data were used to support this study.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare that they have no conflicts of interest.